TECHNOLOGICAL SPILLOVER FROM FDI: EVIDENCE FROM TUNISIAN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
Sami REZGUI (University of Tunis El Manar)
There has been a lot of interesting contributions on technological spillovers
generated by FDI and benefiting to countries and also to firms (R.Caves, 1974,
Wang and Blomstrom 1992, Harrisson and Haddad, 1993, Blomstrom and Sjohlm 1998,
Aitken and Harrisson, 1999, V.Kathuria 2000…). The main purpose of this paper
is to examine to what extent the presence of FDI within a firm and within an
industry could explain a positive evolution of the firm efficiency. Based on
computed indices of total factor productivity (TFP) from Tunisian panel data,
and following Farell's stochastic production frontier's approach (1957) we could
determine the evolution of efficiency at the firm level. We use the Schmidt
and Sickles (1984) approach assuming time-invarying technical efficiency. This
approach could be justified by the short period (1996-1998) considered in this
study.
Using microeconomic data, Harrisson and Haddad (1993) concluded for Morocco
that there was no spillover from foreign investment. Firms' TFP is not affected
by the presence of foreign ownership. The authors used the Schmidt and Sickles
(1984) approach of measuring technical efficiency on panel data. Aitken and
Harrisson (1999) consider quite small the net effect of foreign ownership on
the Venezuelian economy. A positive effect of FDI on TFP is only found in firms
with less than 50 employees and is assumed to be largely internalized by joint
ventures. The authors conclude at the absence of spillovers from FDI benefiting
to domestic firms. For the case of India, V.Kathuria (2000) found that the presence
of foreign owned firms in a sector leads to reduced dispersion in efficiency
mostly for the firms investing in R&D activities. The author used the Cornwell
& ali (1990) approach to estimate time varying technical efficiency levels for
individual firms justified by the period considered (14 years).
Our own hypothesis is that technological spillover from FDI varies and depends
not only on the characteristics of the firm (size of the firm, % of FDI, exports,
Market share, skills), but also on the characteristics of the industry to which
the firm belongs (concentration ratio, foreign capital penetration).
TFP' indices are derived from fixed effects panel data assuming Cobb-Douglas
production function with constant returns to scale (Yijt = aijt
F(Kijt, Lijt) The residual terms (TFP) are derived from
the LS regression :
Log Yijt = log (aijt) + b
log (Xijt) + eijt, Yijt
= output of the firm i belonging to the industry j at time t ; Xijt
= vector of inputs ( Labor and Capital).
According to the Schmidt and Sickles method, relative technical efficiency
at the firm level is measured as follows:
We consider Log aijt as the estimated
TFP of the firm i belonging to the industry j at time t computed in logarithm.
Let log aj be the highest efficiency level
in the industry j for the three years of our study :
Log aj = max [log aijt]
Let qijt = log aijt
- Log aj Þ
(aijt / aj)
= exp (qijt)
Relative Technical Efficiency at the firm level that we note pijt,
is:
pijt = exp (qijt)
= (aijt / aj)
pijt could also be considered as a measure
of the dispersion in productivity. Our purpose is to explain the variation of
pijt. A positive variation of pijt
should be interpreted as a move of the firm toward the efficient frontier.
Let Dpij = pij98
- pij96
We then estimate the following model :
Dpij = F(skills,
market share, export, %FDI, concentration ratio, FDI at the sector level, interactions,
dummies).
We also allow for interaction effects in order to capture the role of the human
factor measured by the skills variable and to measure the intensity of spillovers
linked concomitantly to FDI and to the market structure. Dummies are also used
to capture specific industry effects.
This model is estimated using two digit industry data for 165 firms belonging
mainly to the food, textile and clothing, mechanical and electrical industries,
chemicals, paper and plastic products and cement. We find that technological
spillovers from FDI benefit essentially to small and medium size firms (with
less than 100 employees).