by Soner Songul
A dissertation submitted to the faculty of The University of Utah in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Department of Economics The University of Utah August 2002 Copyright Soner Songul 2002 All Rights Reserved ABSTRACT This dissertation is a descriptive analysis of three selected world currency proposals: Keynes's Bancor Proposal, International Monetary Fund Special Drawing Rights, and Guttmann's Supranational Credit Money Proposal. Specifically, the political economy aspect of these proposals is evaluated. The deficiencies of the current multicurrency arrangement, serving the international monetary system, are the major theme of these proposals. As a part of the investigation into the suggested reforms, many difficulties and benefits of achieving a monetary union are identified. The conclusions of my study put emphasis on the overdraft provisions of the proposals, issues of empowering the central institution through design of enforceable features, importance of maintaining political will of the participant nations, and the desirability of bringing symmetric adjustments to payment balance of individual nations. My thesis is that the current global economy requires an international nonmarket agency for regulating the international monetary system. Implemented, it would provide a multilateral character to international lending and provision of a truly international currency that would serve the increasing integration of economic activities more effectively. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS First, I would like to thank my adviser, Hans Ehrbar, for his continued support and encouragement throughout this work. His insightful comments always led to additional thinking and rewriting for the better. I believe he is a role model for demonstrating how a sincere commitment to a line of thought would display a consistent way of living. I would also like to thank Lance Girton for his challenging questions and keen comments on the material. I would like to extend my gratitude to the other members of my dissertation committee, Gunseli Berik, Al Campbell, Korkut Erturk, and Nedim Alemdar, as well. They all contributed significantly to the content reflecting their extensive knowledge of the issues. To my parents and my sister TABLE OF CONTENTS ABSTRACT ...............................................................iv ACKNOWLEDGMENTS ......................................................viii Chapter 1. INTRODUCTION ................................................ 1 2. CRITICISMS OF THE CURRENT INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM .................... 6 2.1 High Degree of Volatility and the Periodic Misalignment of Exchange Rates .............. 8 2.2 Greater Capital Mobility and Globalization of Financial Markets as a Threat to Systemic Stability .................... 9 2.3 Misallocation of Resources Arising from Uncertainties Associated with Exchange Rate Flexibility ................. 11 2.4 Structure of Decision-making in the Monetary System ....... 13 2.5 The Often Irrational Dynamic of Financial Markets ........... 14 2.6 Large Trade Imbalances Among the Major Industrialized Countries ........................................ 14 2.7 Proposed Solutions ................................................. 15 3. SURVEY OF WORLD CURRENCY PROPOSALS .............. 18 3.1 Keynes's Bancor Proposal ......................................... 18 3.2 Special Drawing Rights ............................................ 28 3.3 Guttmann's SNCM Proposal ...................................... 34 4. COUNTERARGUMENTS AGAINST WORLD CURRENCY PROPOSALS ............................ 40 5. POLITICAL ECONOMY ASPECTS OF THE WORLD CURRENCY PROPOSALS ................. 47 5.1 Political Economy of International Monetary Relations ...... 48 5.2 Political Economy of Monetary Unions ......................... 54 5.2.1 Economic Benefits and Costs ............................... 57 5.2.2 Currency Domain in relation to the Fiscal and Trade Domains ........................... 60 5.2.2.1 Does a single currency scheme require fiscal federalism? ................................... 60 5.2.2.2 Is a single currency needed to support fiscal federalism? ................................... 62 5.2.2.3 Interactions between currency regimes and trade policies ................................... 65 5.2.3 The Transition to Monetary Union ......................... 65 5.3 Political Economy Aspects of the World Currency Proposals ................................ 69 5.3.1 Keynes's Bancor Proposal ................................... 69 5.3.2 Special Drawing Rights ...................................... 74 5.3.3 Guttmann's SNCM Proposal ................................. 78 6. CONCLUSION ....................................................... 81 REFERENCES ............................................................... 96 CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION Discussions of the international monetary arrangements intensify every time a crisis hits the world economy. Political power relations, using the dominant frame of thinking, shape economic institutions that come about after these discussions. Subsequent performance of the world economy is intimately connected to the outcome of these efforts. Most recently, the 1997-1998 Asian crisis retriggered attempts to analyze global connections between monetary measures and the real side of the economy. After the Great Depression and during the Second World War the Bretton Woods Conference signified a collective effort to plan the monetary scheme in attempt to avoid the recurrence of the Great Depression. Keynes's Bancor proposal represents the position of one of the two most dominant negotiating nations, Britain. Despite being shelved, it has a striking resemblance to some more recent international system reform proposals (for example, Davidson and Guttmann). This study investigates the potential of world currency proposals with an emphasis on the surrounding political economy aspects. Unfortunately, this is not a world where political struggles have been replaced with conflict resolution intended to benefit everyone. Even in situations where cooperation would clearly enhance the outcome for all involved parties, a joint solution may not be reached, due to the negotiation process, priorities of individual participant nations (for the sake of coalition building), and repercussions on domestic politics. It is understandable that policymakers are responsible for protecting the welfare of their constituents. What is missing appears to be recognition of interconnectedness among nations and the potential for betterment and progress, while respecting similar rights of others. Greater integration of world economic activity is a characteristic of the postwar development of the world economy. This market globalization was accompanied by various disputes among the nations that remained the political units of managing affairs. Despite widespread impacts of individual nations' policies on others, domestic policies have primarily been motivated by domestic concerns. In the realm of monetary policies, for the most part, national central banks are doing a good job responding to the needs of domestic economies. However, prospects of international contagion usually present a real challenge to national policymakers during crisis times. This creates a need to look at the institutional framework of international monetary affairs. Policymakers are challenged on several fronts in connection with the globalization of economic activity. Capital accumulation has a tendency to go beyond national borders in all aspects: finance, production and exchange. However, these aspects expand at different paces and scope, causing concern about coordination of the activities. It should not come as a surprise to see that both Marx and Keynes placed an analysis of money at the heart of their own capitalism studies. Money represents a social mechanism for the coordination of all productive activities and social validation of output. Viewing the current international monetary system, there are multiple lines of inquiries observing deficiencies of the whole structure. Several deficiencies are observed while using multiple national currencies for international roles. These deficits include high degree of volatility and periodic misalignment of exchange rates, globalization of financial markets and capital mobility as possible threats to systemic stability, misallocation of resources arising from uncertainties associated with exchange rate flexibility, concerns regarding the structure of monetary system decision-making, financial market dynamics (with its often irrational outcomes), and persistence of large trade imbalances among the major industrialized countries. Among others, Schulmeister (2000) draws attention to the double role of the key currencies as a major contributor to the emergence of crisis situations. Oftentimes the double role, in national and international affairs, results in multiple conflicts between the two roles being played. This position establishes the starting point of world currency proposals. More considerations in relation to the current system will be discussed in the second chapter. One significant criticism against the world currency proposals is their supposed irrelevance to the current actual situation. This can be grounded in the belief that the existing political forces will not allow a truly international currency to replace the already dominant currencies. It is true that the U.S. Treasury is capable of blocking any increase in international lending shares of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and World Bank therefore employing a definite favoritism to big private lenders, instead of international organizations. However, it would be impossible to guess how soon the balance of power might shift and preferences could be adjusted accordingly by individual nations. Just watching the European Monetary Union improving provides some clues about rejecting the impossibility hypothesis, since those countries are apparently willing to give up their mostly credible national currencies in favor of a joint currency created from scratch. This dissertation will focus primarily on three of the world currency initiatives. Those are Keynes's Bancor plan, IMF's Special Drawing Rights (SDR) and Guttmann's Supranational Credit Money proposal. In the meantime, some consideration will also be given to Davidson's plan. After introducing these world currency proposals in Chapter 3, an examination of the major criticisms against these three plans will follow in Chapter 4, and the fifth chapter will investigate the political economy aspects relating to these proposals. The fifth chapter is particularly important and constitutes the primary contribution of this study. Whenever a substantial change of the whole system is introduced, the first line of criticism usually has connections to the existent political structure. It is no different in the case of world currency proposals. As opposed to the usual approach for modifying the system in an incremental fashion, all of these propositions aim at restructuring the whole framework, so that the functioning of the international monetary system will be altogether altered. The ambition supporting this lies in the goal of achieving a new configuration so that (at least) some of the disparities will be eliminated. The implications of such a big change would naturally cause a stir in the political side of the account. Some common points of concern in relation to monetary unification include loss of monetary autonomy, distribution of seigniorage benefits, and symbolic significance of national currencies. There are numerous issues raised in connection with relationships between the currency domain and fiscal and trade domains. Further, there are additional difficulties associated with transition from the current system to a common currency. All of these many aspects will be considered in Chapter 5; first in relation to monetary unions (in general) and then in relation to the studied plans. Finally, crucial elements are identified from conclusions of the considered proposals with special emphasis given to central international institution empowerment and overdraft provisions. These two aspects deserve special attention. The latter constitutes a main point of contention, relating to the fundamental issue of how much creditors want to try a new structure, essentially promising a more stable system. In return they are likely to suffer a loss in their power to decide who gets the funds. The former issue is important for relating to possible plan success/failure at implementation. The SDR experience specifically indicates how the actual functioning can be stalled in many different ways, e.g., a veto power obtained by a country or a group of countries, possible usage of unintelligible language at the initial stage (defining the operation), or connection to design of the governing board not leading to promotion of IMF policies, even by participant nations. Each of these characteristics is crucial to deciding the outcome of the initiative. The next chapter will provide an overview of the criticisms of the current international monetary system. Thereby a brief evaluation of the current system's functioning will set the stage for the world currency proposals that will be introduced in the following chapter. CHAPTER 2 CRITICISMS OF THE CURRENT INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM International monetary relations have been a favorite conference theme throughout history. Both political and economic aspects are considered in these thoughtful and challenging discussions. Not only are they debatable at international meetings, but also numerous academic studies attempt to build a better understanding of monetary relationships among nations. Any analysis should start with an assessment of the current state of affairs, in order to establish meaningful connections. In this study, before investigating world currency proposals aiming to improve performance of the world economy and international monetary system, we will discuss criticisms of the international monetary system that indicate current concerns. Today's world economy is characterized by increasing internationalization of world markets. One of the first questions tackled by many is the extent of economic integration (Bryant 1990, p.16; Rodrik 1998, p.4). Rodrik observes a `home bias' in asset portfolios and concludes that asset markets are not yet tightly integrated. Guttmann argues that the pace and scope of integration process has yielded a qualitatively different economic environment (1994, p.324). While describing these qualitative attributes, he notes an inherent tendency for capital accumulation expansion beyond national borders in all aspects: exchange, production and finance. However, a lack of coordination in expansion of these activities is observed. In comparison to the national economies, global economy has some unique structural features. Guttmann (1994) identifies these as lacking a fully developed state apparatus (also Bryant 1990, p.18), foreign trade involving a second transaction (currency conversion), and the need for a mechanism for symmetric adjustments and even development. All three aspects signify that any analysis of the world economy should pay special attention to the nature of interactions in between the existing political units. Since a supranational structure to foresee the overall picture is nonexistent, efforts for extended cooperation need to overcome objections of individual nations. Accordingly, challenges in the international monetary sphere would need to address political issues in consideration of implementation difficulties. We could extend our investigation of the current state of affairs by asking many other crucial questions, such as: Does globalization aggravate inequality? How significant are the benefits of globalization? How much does globalization constrain national autonomy? Each question is individually significant and demands attention, but the focus of this dissertation relates to monetary affairs so we will now turn to some criticisms of the current international monetary system. In order to pave the way for expectations of the international monetary system, it would be appropriate to direct attention to criticisms of the current system. Next, some common themes will be listed with some brief explanations of relevant criticisms. 2.1 High Degree of Volatility and the Periodic Misalignment of Exchange Rates Lack of flexibility was seen as a critical deficiency of the Bretton Woods system (DeGrauwe 1996, p.244). It was hoped that with flexible exchange rates depreciations and appreciations of the currency would help smooth the correction of current account deficits and surpluses. Flexible exchange rates were proposed to achieve international trade balances through adjustments in these exchange rates and to provide national authorities with partial relief from the maintenance efforts of fixed exchange rates. However, the experience brought a high degree of instability to the international monetary system, due to large fluctuations in exchange rates. Looking at the time series data of major industrialized countries the current account imbalances increased ever since the flexible exchange rates were adopted. In particular, the dollar exchange rate is observed to fluctuate even more than other reserve currencies (Schulmeister 2000, p.365). The oil shocks of the 1970s are cited among some of the explanations for persistent current account imbalances (DeGrauwe 1996, p.245). However, experience in the 1980s has been ever-increasing current account imbalances, well after the current account effects of the oil shocks have diffused. Lack of coordination among the countries' fiscal policies is suggested as a second possible theory. It has been argued that the presence of flexible exchange rates gives fiscal policy authorities incentive to pursue more independent policies that lead to divergent patterns of national fiscal policies (DeGrauwe 1996, p.246). Thirdly, the low price elasticity of trade volumes is given as possible cause of increasing current account imbalances just after exchange rate adjustments. The existence of so-called `J curves' describes this lag of volume response to price changes. When exchange rate movements are perceived as transitory, the trade flows are argued to be less responsive to exchange rate variations (DeGrauwe 1996, p.247). As another alternative, Schulmeister develops an analysis tying developments in the postwar era to the double role of the dollar, and inward oriented policies of the U.S. (2000, p.366). In contrast to flexible exchange rates, fixed exchange arrangements are noted to have possible troubles based on the following premises. Credible commitments by national authorities for exchange rate targets are seen as unlikely, since domestic objectives may conflict with these commitments (DeGrauwe 1996, p.55). Without political and institutional integration, a joint monetary policy would be unworkable. European integration presents a case attempting to introduce such new institutional frameworks, including elements of political integration. Given the experiences from the 1970s to the 1990s, flexible exchange rates bring a high degree of volatility to the world monetary system (Cooper 1990, p.289). The recurring misalignments forced significant adjustments between the tradable and nontradable sectors of many countries (DeGrauwe 1996, p.252). 2.2 Greater Capital Mobility and Globalization of Financial Markets as a Threat to Systemic Stability `While exchange-rate volatility affects both industrial and developing countries, mainly developing countries suffer from capital-flow volatility' (Gunter 1996, p.115). In support of the exchange rate section of this argument, DeGrauwe (1988) found that exchange-rate variability explains 20 percent of the slowdown in world trade growth since 1973. The growth rate of world trade is not the only concern in relation to exchange rate fluctuations, but it is sufficient to demonstrate that impact is experienced by all (for the most part). In consideration of capital flows, we should note that the direction of funds is, to a great extent, determined in financial markets by fund managers and investors. Beliefs are formed in these markets within informational constraints on possible returns among alternatives. Over time, these beliefs are subject to revisions with new information and speculation shaping perceptions; Capital markets are regarded as highly vulnerable. As the Asian crisis exemplified most recently (Hahnel 1999), whenever a sharp reversal of funds occurs, the developing countries are left with the detrimental consequences of the financial crisis. Individual countries' ability to sustain economic stability and stability in world economy as a whole (to some extent) depends on how successfully they deal with speculative `hot money' that flows in and out of currencies. Hence, one of the desired features for the monetary system is finding structure that will discourage speculation. The principle of comparative advantage suggests an international division of labor through a relatively free movement of goods and services between countries. This century-old trade theory accommodated capital flows, expecting movements of capital to allocate financial resources for real investments anywhere (Roosa 1989, p.257). This physical capital formation would nourish a more diversified worldwide growth by means of highly integrated capital markets. In contrast to this vision, the superstructure of investments and currencies yielded a picture where a dominant proportion of capital movements reflected attempts of portfolio diversification (Guttmann 1989a, p.17). Consequently, fluctuations in interest rates or appraisals of exchange rates brought the impetus for shifts of portfolio capital. Such structure of capital movements translates into tendencies toward more economic instability for individual countries and transmission of troubles to other countries by means of capital markets. There are conflicting views regarding capital controls. For example, IMF still sustains the view that they are contrary to efficient resource allocation. Only recently, IMF seemed to view capital controls as transitory measures (IMF, 1995). Still, there are views in support of protection by capital controls, as they helped Chile and Colombia during the 1994 Mexican peso crisis (Gunter 1996, p.118). Another proposal for reducing capital market volatility is called Tobin tax. This is a tax on all foreign-exchange transactions. Though it is argued to be technically feasible (Arestis and Sawyer 1997), political obstacles work against an introduction. And, it is regarded as a second-best option by even Tobin himself (Gunter 1996, p.119). Gunter argues for a world central bank as the best solution. Until this can be established, using Tobin tax, selective capital controls and a set of regulatory and supervisory responses seems appropriate. However, Cooper thinks the impact of such a tax on short-term exchange rate volatility is entirely unclear (1990, p.292). 2.3 Misallocation of Resources Arising From Uncertainties Associated with Exchange Rate Flexibility Cooper presents the main features of this interaction with the following list of possible ways exchange rates influence the allocation of resources (Cooper, 1990, pp.286-288). First, a high variability of exchange rates would reduce investment in the sectors with intense international competition. Not knowing how long depreciation of currency will last would leave firms hesitant to add productive capacity of tradables. Second, major adjustments to external disturbances may require changes in the overall price level of a country. If the government takes a contrary action by targeting the price level, adjustment via price level to external disturbance would be obstructed. In due course, the composition and level of the output would be changed in response to pursued policies. Third, imperfect competition would imply that fixed market entry or market exit costs may avoid adjustments in relation to exchange rate fluctuations. No adjustment would take place until the exchange rate fluctuation exceeds a certain threshold, making exit or entry worthwhile for firms. Fourth, since firms are unable to hedge future production of investments against exchange rate fluctuations, they may simply prefer to invest abroad (across currency zones), even when producing at a low-cost location could bring cost and scale advantages. Fifth, fluctuations in exchange rates may reflect onto domestic firms as unfair competition from abroad and they may seek protection from their government. Resultantly, increasing trade barriers would alter mix of output. All the above connections suggest a misallocation of resources in relation to exchange rate fluctuations and uncertainty. Improving the current monetary arrangements for a better environment to help decisions of current and future production is necessary. 2.4 Structure of Decision-making in the Monetary System Sustaining a satisfactory flow of capital to needy countries and correction of the balance of payments imbalances have been two of the issues addressed in connection with how international flow of funds are decided. The former aims at finding a way of reducing the development gap through a better allocation of funds. The latter issue is critical in maintaining long-term sustainability of the whole system. As noted above, currently the question of how distribution of funds happens is answered in the financial markets for the most part. In terms of capital flowing through governments or some international organizations, like IMF, World Bank and so on, a two-way interaction with the markets is in place. There are doubts about how observed flow patterns in the markets can be explained as rational decisions. Further, the allocation of funds by IMF and World Bank is also subject to some criticism. These institutions are accused of excluding some countries for political reasons, even when economic criteria would suggest the opposite (The Economist, 1991, p.46). Currently, the share of official institutions in international lending remains very small in comparison to private lenders. This fact is directly correlated with U.S. polices favoring private bank involvement. United States Treasury effectively blocks initiatives to increase the IMF and World Bank's share of international lending. However, the resultant private bank lending is highly susceptible to the moral hazard problem (Lance Girton, private conversations, May 2001). The prospect of being bailed out every time a big failure occurs motivates big private lenders to avoid smaller countries and projects, although funding them would reduce risk through diversification. Consequently, recurring crisis situations emerge at the same time efficiency and equity are sacrificed. Inability of the poorest countries to access international funds suggests a better way of distributing funds should be possible. 2.5 The Often Irrational Dynamic of Financial Markets Social psychological dynamics of markets may cause patterns of behavior that may not correspond to economic basis. Following the trend may cause market participants to pay less than adequate attention to the underlying fundamentals (Cooper 1990, p.290). Thus, process of forming expectations will likely add to volatility in exchange rate markets. Consequently, production and investment decisions are left with higher uncertainty stemming from foreign-exchange markets and international capital markets. 2.6 Large Trade Imbalances Among the Major Industrialized Countries As Cooper notes, `There is no special merit in assuring balance in each country's current account position'(1990, p.282) and `...we do not have a clear operational definition of international equilibrium' (1990, p.283). However, huge trade imbalances among the major industrialized countries present the possibility of exchange rate misalignments for currencies being used as international money. The fact that the U.S. runs trade deficits and finances these trade deficits through capital inflows, creates a potentially unstable situation because stability of global economy is tied to foreign confidence in dollar-denominated assets (Guttmann 1989b, p.219). This was exactly the same scenario that led Triffin to conclude that an international currency should be used (1960). As Guttmann argues, it would be reasonable for less-developed countries to use foreign funds for their real investments and experience payment deficits as they catch up. The current picture significantly exhibits the opposite in terms of payment balances, not promising much development convergence among countries. 2.7 Proposed Solutions The above questions can be discussed in relation to current international currency arrangements. Within the current system, a few national currencies play significant international roles and this fact leads to connection inquiries. Schulmeister (2000) points out that the double role of the dollar assigns substantial importance to interest rates and exchange rates of the dollar. As world currency, changes in dollar interest rates and exchange rates reflect onto `...relative price between commodities and manufactures in world trade, the terms of trade between industrial and developing countries, the speed of inflation and deflation in world trade and the level of real interest rate on international debts' (Schulmeister 2000, p.366). Through an analysis of dollar exchange rate and interest rate fluctuations, he demonstrates that postwar development was shaped by the contradictory relationship between the dollar's two roles as a national currency and as a world currency. There are several solutions proposed in response to the above problems. Next, a brief overview of suggested arrangements will be presented. The first of these is the so-called Tobin tax, a transactions tax on foreign exchange conversions, introduced above in connection with high capital mobility of the current system. As noted, it is regarded to be a second-best option, and there are some concerns of diverting attention from the need of more radical changes in the exchange rate system, thus delaying implementation of such changes (Gunter 1996, p.119). Another proposal seeks stability in the foreign exchange markets by setting target zones for major currencies' exchange rates. Williamson's and Kenen's names are associated with this proposal (Gunter 1996; Cooper 1990). Possible problems with such a system are technical difficulties in determining correct fundamental exchange rates and an inability to avoid short run volatility if target zones are not set quite narrowly. As they did for the European Monetary System, target zones might serve as a first step. However, they must be brought together with increased coordination surveillance and disclosure policies (Gunter 1996, p.121). Cooper proposes the initial institution of a single currency by Japan, European Union, and the U.S. (1990). The other countries would join later. He emphasizes that disturbances to the real productive side of national economies stem from nominal exchange rate flexibility, to a significant extent. Gunter argues that the current international monetary system is not sustainable, primarily in connection with exchange-rate volatility and speculative attacks on currencies (1996). He believes that global solutions are necessary. He addresses objections to the World Central Bank idea and draws up a new development vision that includes a World Central Bank. Lietaer proposes a commodity-based global reference currency (1996) with a demurrage charge. His inferences from some historical examples and his discussion of impact on business cycle, employment, inflation, ecology and international business do not seem very convincing. The proposals to be examined in this study are Keynes's Bancor proposal, Davidson's proposal, and Guttmann's proposal, alongside the experience of SDR. These proposals all concern attempts to institute an international currency managed by an international agency. What is striking about them is the identification of problems in the current system at a very fundamental level. They all attempt response to the predicament of having few national currencies serve the double role of national currency and world currency, at the same time. Envisioning the possibility of a truly international currency is challenging; discovering what part of the current problems are to be attributed to the system's daily functioning, and what part belongs to design. Since these proposals are usually dismissed for political reasons, it is especially worthwhile to consider the political economy aspects. In the next chapter, the aforementioned proposals will be introduced, while an investigation into their political economy aspects will be pursued in the fifth chapter. CHAPTER 3 SURVEY OF WORLD CURRENCY PROPOSALS This chapter introduces the three world currency proposals to be compared in this dissertation: Keynes's Bancor proposal, SDR of IMF, and Guttmann's Supranational Credit Money (SNCM) proposal. This order also indicates the order of historical emergence. Presenting them in this fashion allows for following the development of features of the international monetary system over the years. 3.1 Keynes's Bancor Proposal Keynes's Bancor plan was brought to the table at the Bretton Woods Conference. Discussions of this plan took place (especially in Britain) during years preceding the conference, and there is documentation of those deliberations. More recent Post-Keynesian proposals (Davidson 1992, 1998; Guttmann 1994) resemble the Bancor plan to some degree. In this chapter Keynes's Bancor plan will be introduced alongside Davidson's proposal. Such a comparative presentation should provide insights into basics of the two and yield some indication of changing concerns. An initial description of the frame of mind behind these proposals is worth mentioning, as one feature common to both Keynes's and Davidson's presentation of their own ideas. Paul Davidson presents his proposal as `...a basis for the beginning of a sound analytical discussion.' (1992) This attitude resembles the way Keynes's Bancor proposal was brought to the table at the Bretton Woods negotiations. It also embraced an open-to-suggestions type of presentation. Although both strongly believe in the virtues of their plans, they prefer to open the doors of negotiation, without being over-assertive. This appears to be the correct attitude when proposing an ambitious plan for changing many critical features of the system. With intention to reform groundwork for the international economic system, Keynes identifies a list of conditions to prove a system long lasting: (i)...[I]n the realm of internal policy the authority of the governing board of the proposed institution should be limited to recommendations, or at the most to imposing conditions for the more extended enjoyment of the facilities which the institution offers. (ii) The technique of the plan must be capable of application, irrespective of the type and principle of government and economic policy existing in the prospective member states. (iii) ... management of the institution must be genuinely international without preponderant power of veto or enforcement to any country or group; and the rights and the privileges of the smaller countries must be safeguarded. (iv) ... provision must be made for voiding the obligation at due notice. (v) [T]he plan must operate not only to the general advantage but also to the individual advantage of each of the participants and must not require a special economic or financial sacrifice from certain countries. No participant should be asked to do or offer anything which is not to his own true long-term interest. (Keynes 1943, p.56) Through these conditions, Keynes introduces a short list of essential features to be met before offering the details of his plan. Since he served as a member of the British delegation on different occasions, it is no surprise to see such a presentation as it demonstrates an awareness of themes likely to face any such structural change. The above conditions address some basic concerns for participant countries and indicate acknowledgment of associated requirements. Primacy of nations' internal politics in evaluating this plan is the common theme in all above arguments. For his plan, Keynes introduces an analogy with a national banking system (Keynes 1943, p.66). A national banking system provides means for utilizing funds of depositors to finance business elsewhere, so that balances are not left idle. Similarly, the International Clearing Union (ICU) provides a multilateral clearing system that provides a credit mechanism in place of hoarding funds. As an alternative to multilateral clearing, bilateral arrangements (for providing international overdrafts) would bring greater complexity and likely impacts of extraneous political reasons (like those noted by Viner (1929)). Keynes repeatedly stressed usefulness of the `impersonal' lending attribute of proposed facilities, particularly in transitional period after war. Wray argues that Keynes's banking analogy is flawed (1998). Although Keynes indicates that existence of ICU forms the basis for loaning money, Wray contends the loans of Bancors create the Bancor reserves. He attributes the plan's expansionary character to reduction in exchange rate uncertainty. He suggests the analogy be made with capitalist countries moving from `mutual funds money' to `par money,' based on gold reserves and later based on Central Bank reserves. He argues that recent movement from gold standard to flexible exchange rates in the international sphere represents a backward step. Wray's criticism is an effort to put developments in perspective alongside a general query into the nature of money. Wray's contention is noteworthy, since probably the majority of who is interested in monetary issues has a basic curiosity regarding these questions. Hence, if the unit of account function of money is the key to understanding its significance then it would be this function to promote the acceptability of a newly introduced currency. For example, this would imply that it would be useful to denominate all contracts in Euros as well as national currencies during the last stage of transition into common currency. Returning to our discussion of Keynes's proposal, he discusses properties sought for the system of international currency as a means of setting the stage for his plan objectives. He calls for: (a) An international currency instrument to be employed in transactions with other nations. A general acceptability of this instrument among nations would be a necessary condition. (b) A method for determining relative exchange rates. Rules must be agreed upon to prevent competitive exchange rate devaluations through unilateral decisions. (c) A quantum of value, capable of responding to the needs of world economy with deliberate expansionary and contractionary states in response to the deflationary and inflationary tendencies apparent in world demand. (d) A mechanism maintaining internal stability by exercising pressure on any country to correct departures from payments equilibrium in either direction. (e) A system capable of providing a stock of reserves to every country after war to help during the transition to peacetime conditions. (f) A central institution to aid and cooperate in planning and regulating the world economy. A purely technical and nonpolitical character is expected to hold true for this institution. These conditions stand as a statement of concern for stability of the system, and the appeal of a central institution to watch currency needs and the general economic state of the world. Keynes's plan names Bancor, an international bank-money, for settling international balances. The value of a Bancor would be set in reference to gold. Member state Central Banks would be entitled to settle their exchange balances (in terms of Bancors) through their accounts at ICU. Prevention of credit or debit balances accumulating would be a prerequisite for long-run system sustainability. Keynes suggests that a governing board of ICU be appointed by several member state governments. A quota for each country would be determined for the usage of the Union's credit facilities, as well as the country's responsibility in managing the Union. As an initial proposition, Keynes argues that quotas be determined in relation to individual countries' trade volume, while also possibly employing other factors. Member states are allowed to overdraw Bancors up to their quotas. A member state is required to pay 1 percent annually on its average balance of Bancors in excess of one quarter of its total quota. This payment increases to 2 percent for the average balance in excess of half the allotted quota. Countries would be allowed to avoid these contributions to the Reserve Fund if they decide to help each other after governing board consultations. Excessive use of interest-laden borrowing arrangements would probably be restricted at this consultation stage, because allowing for extensive bilateral arrangements among the member states would be rendering the enforcement mechanism ineffective when faced with payment disequilibria. Therefore, a limitation on bilateral cancellations would be necessary for restraining international payment disequilibria. According to Keynes's plan, the following measures suggest relief of debit balances: devaluation of currency, control of outward capital transactions, and outright surrender of gold or other liquid assets. In case of credit balance, measures include expansion of domestic credit and demand, appreciation of currency, reduction of tariffs against imports, and international development loans. As the value of Bancor is defined and fixed in terms of gold, member states are asked to not buy gold at a higher price than the parity. Convertibility of gold into Bancors is possible, while demanding gold for Bancor balances is prohibited. This stipulation leaves discretion of distributing excess gold balances to the governing board, while ruling out possibility of a rush for gold reserves of ICU. Wray adopts similar reasoning to explain this one-way convertibility arrangement (1998). Nonmember state central banks are allowed to have credit clearing accounts for their trade with member states, but they would not have access to overdraft facilities or any say in ICU management. Keynes claims the following advantages for his plan: - - an expansionist pressure on world trade, - - overdraft facilities providing relief for some countries without burdening others, - - credit substituting for hoarding, to resemble the national banking system, - - multilateral character of international overdraft arrangements, - - provision of a mechanism to counter disequilibria, - - setting adjustment responsibility on the creditor, as well as debtor nations. About five decades later, Davidson came out with his proposal that primarily endorses Keynes's analysis (1992). He recognizes more than simply choosing between fixed and flexible exchange rate regimes is required in effort to restructure the international monetary system. He claims the targets as forming a mechanism to resolve payment imbalances while promoting full employment, economic growth, and a stable international standard of value. Similar to Keynes's plan, Davidson votes for a fixed (yet adjustable) exchange rate system, combined with requiring surplus trading nations to share the burden of adjustment for payments imbalances. The concern is persistent current account imbalances among trading partners, leading to an inability to promote continuous global economic expansion. This emphasis on payment balance corrections fits exactly with the Solomon (1996) and Triffin (1985) descriptions of changing concerns in the 1970s. Davidson's plan has provisions that appear to target objectives similar to Keynes. He states that his plan aims for: (1) prevention of lacking global effective demand, (2) an automatic mechanism to place a major burden of payment adjustments onto surplus nations, (3) ability to monitor and control movements of flight capital for each nation, (4) ability to expand quantity of international currency, as global capacity necessitates. In terms of provisions, Davidson's plan shares elements with Keynes's Bancor plan. It would introduce an overdraft system, making short-term credit balances available to finance productive international transactions. Further, a trigger mechanism would be instituted so that creditor nations are encouraged to spend excessive credit balances. Davidson's International Money Clearing Unit (IMCU) resembles Bancor, given the role to facilitate transactions through the International Clearing Union. IMCU accounts will be held by central banks, while member central banks will guarantee one-way convertibility from IMCU deposits to their domestic currencies. This provision avoids possible draining of national currency reserves from the system. Davidson's plan has this one-way convertibility arrangement in a similar fashion but defined somewhat differently than what Keynes argued for with gold-Bancor convertibility. Davidson obliges national central banks for providing their national currency when requested by ICU. Both of these convertibility limitations aim at avoiding unilateral actions of individual countries that might leave ICU without gold reserves or domestic currencies. Exchange rates between IMCU and domestic currencies will be fixed, yet subject to future modifications. One cause for change in the exchange rate would occur after a permanent increase in efficiency wages of a country. Davidson's plan recognizes two basic options for that nation in case of such productivity increase. These are appreciation of domestic currency, or keeping the nominal exchange rate as it is to attain an increasing share of the world market for its export industries. As for the opposite, if a rich country experiences persistent current account deficits when at full employment, rules of the plan require a devaluation of its exchange rate over a period to eliminate imbalance - without inducing significant recessionary forces. If a poor nation has a current account deficit, support through other nations' excess credit balance transfers would be an option. Davidson deems a supranational central bank infeasible (in reference to the world politics) and his proposal does not include it. However, in his proposal, an international institution, sounding very similar to Keynes' Clearing Union idea, still holds central position. Next, a brief discussion of some criticisms of these plans will be introduced. First, will be Triffin's concerns relating to Keynes's plan. Then Wray's comments will provide a Post-Keynesian vision in criticizing Keynes's and Davidson's plans. Triffin (1957) offered three main criticisms of the Keynes's plan regarding limitations on convertibility, distribution of voting power, size and automaticity of borrowing rights and lending commitments. All these elements represent the principal themes of subsequent disagreements. The plan required commitment from each member to leave the value of its currency in terms of Bancor unaltered and not to acquire gold in excess of parity. With the provision permitting all members to acquire another currency through Bancor transfers, the plan would have outlawed and made generalization of bilateral trade and payment agreements impossible, which in fact characterized the early postwar years. Hence, convertibility limitations attracted some opposition to the Bancor plan. With disproportionate voting power of the sterling area, another issue emerged. The initial proposition of basing voting power in proportion to quotas would take the countries' average trade turnover as base. That would grant 30 percent of the total voting power to the sterling area, opposed to 12 percent for the United States. Keynes is noted to accommodate U.S. opposition by agreeing in advance to substitute this formula with `a special assessment,' as deemed necessary. The proposed size of borrowing quotas would be adjusted over time, in accordance with average trade turnover. This raised criticisms about the inflationary bias of the formula. Triffin notes that British proposals were designed for initial bargaining positions. As for automaticity of lending, the creditor nations were not as willing to accept a system of `impersonal' lending. National lending had been, and still is, an instrument of national power and an adjunct to diplomacy. Wray's criticisms have their roots in the post-Keynesian view of money. Opposing the orthodox view of money emphasizing the medium of exchange function, post-Keynesian view highlights the origin of money to lie with the unit of account function of money (Wray 1998). According to Wray, times of existential uncertainty and private property led to the possibility of loan and emergence of money. The endogenous money approach proposes that quantity of money be determined in debt contracts, denominated in money terms as a unit of account. This perspective takes us to Wray's first criticism of Keynes's presentation of the Bancor proposal. He sees efforts to put the medium of exchange function at the forefront a mistake. Essentially, he claims, designing an International Monetary System, as if trade is performed as `goods against goods,' is flawed. In any capitalist economy, position taking in assets those are expected to generate gross income (in monetary terms) is a fundamental activity. Wray states that Keynes's and Davidson's plans aim at eliminating the speculative attacks on currencies arising from flexible exchange rates. Such a change would remove expected appreciation or depreciation component from expectations of returns on foreign assets. Consequently, that would be conducive to a more stable International Monetary System. One can also propose that fixing exchange rates would be more conducive to speculative attacks. Therefore validity of either side hinges upon an assessment of whether market forces themselves are leading to attacks on currencies or are efforts for maintaining fixed exchange rates leading to credibility issues and possible attacks on currencies. Wray's second criticism discusses Keynes's banking analogy as confusion. This criticism was introduced previously in connection with Keynes' initial presentation of the plan. 3.2 Special Drawing Rights When national currencies are used to meet global liquidity needs, rapid growth of trade and investment can be sustained only through payment deficits by the key currency countries. Triffin emphasized that this would inevitably raise doubts in regard to the quality of those currencies (1960). Thereby, he argued for inherent inadequacy of national currencies as world money, which indicated need for a new liquidity device. A decade after Triffin's initial proposal, in 1967 industrial nations agreed to the introduction of Special Drawing Rights (SDR) to be issued by IMF. The emergence of SDR represents the only historical world currency experience and deserves a comprehensive examination to discover the issues surrounding it. Cumby (1983) provides a thorough overview of the international monetary system and proposals for reform prior to the Rio Agreement, which instituted SDR in 1967. Intellectual background supporting incubation of the Rio Agreement include three major concerns: reserve adequacy, asymmetries, and confidence problem. Triffin introduced the notion of reserve adequacy as the ratio of reserves to imports, assuming the reserve demand grows with world trade (1947). He used this measure to compare reserve adequacy over time and across countries (1960). Based on this analysis, Triffin predicted a prospective gold shortage. However, claims of reserve inadequacy were challenged in reference to possible controlling of liquidity growth connected with price level increase concerns. The measurement of reserve adequacy was refined to include variability of export receipts and by identifying it as a ratio to net external balance rather than imports. On the other hand, it was noted that a country's willingness to adjust external balances by using exchange rates would reduce reserves demand. Under such a managed floating exchange rate arrangement, individual country reserve demands also had this additional dimension. Cumby concluded (in reference to Clower and Lipsey, 1968) `... measures of adequacy based on trade data were insufficient and ... making an assessment of adequacy under a policy regime that encouraged speculation against the authorities was impossible without an understanding of the economics and psychology of speculative crises' (1983, p.439). This statement appears more like a confession of inability to specify the structural forces determining the demand for reserves and pointing to the connection of speculation. Reserve adequacy was only one of the issues discussed. The confidence problem was raised as an issue to follow. Again, it is attributed to Triffin's (1960) analysis of the gold-exchange standard's instability. If the growth of reserve demand, in excess of increases in gold supply, were to be satisfied through increased official dollar claims, the confidence in the fixed dollar price of gold would be challenged. Cumby observes that prior to the Rio agreement, gold-conversion decisions of central banks were influenced by both political and portfolio considerations (1983, p.440). In addition to the military power of the United States, the common interest in maintaining stability of the international monetary system kept many countries away from converting dollars into gold. The existence of asymmetries in the system was another issue addressed in the literature. The first asymmetry relates to the United States facing no reserve constraints while formulating its fiscal and monetary policies. Triffin states, in retrospect, that in 1960 he placed too much emphasis on potential reserve inadequacy, but insufficient emphasis on this asymmetry (1978). Literature of the late 1960s recognized the central role of the dollar primarily indicated that U.S. policy determined the level of world aggregate demand, while others argued it manifested through determining the world interest rates; leaving the other countries with a choice of their interest differentials with the dollar to influence capital flows (Cumby 1983, p.441). It is possible to argue that the manifestation of this asymmetry is possible through either monetary or fiscal means. A second asymmetry of the system involved assignment of responsibility for correcting payment imbalances to deficit countries. Deficit countries lacked the ability to sterilize the impact on the monetary base as they faced a loss of reserves. On the other hand, surplus countries could insulate the monetary base (at least in the short run) against the effects of payment imbalances (Cumby 1983, p.442). Despite pressures from developing countries, proposals to create a link between reserve creation and development finance were denied and SDRs were distributed in proportion to IMF quotas. As Buira indicates (1996, p.192), the main industrial countries received the bulk of SDR allocations, as they command the largest quotas. On the other hand, low-income countries received only a small proportion even though they have the greatest need to augment their reserves. Williamson concurs with this observation and argues strongly in favor of a new allocation of SDRs (1984). His reasoning includes, but is not limited to, debt relief for oil importing developing countries. Oil exporting developing countries, the United States, and the other industrialized countries would reap the mostly indirect benefits by defusing the debt crisis. He notes `(t)he purpose of inventing the SDR system was ... exactly to allow countries to accumulate reserves in the medium term without a net export of real resources or foreign borrowing' (1984, p.26). Providing reserves to hold, rather than to spend, without generating inflationary pressures was the original objective of the SDR system (1984, p.2). Next, a few features of the SDR scheme will be listed to characterize its operation at a basic level. IMF's SDR department keeps record of each country's SDR allocation and current holding. A country can use its SDR balances by exchanging them for other currencies. It can find another country to do the transaction, or may ask IMF to find one. In response, IMF can provide the currency from its own holdings, or can designate another country to provide the currency requested. Every country is obliged to accept SDR in exchange of currencies, up to 300 percent of their net cumulative allocations. Allocations of SDR are made in proportion to the shares of individual countries' IMF quotas. Value of an SDR is defined as equaling a basket of five major currencies. The intention is to minimize arbitrary variations, in real value of international assets and liabilities, so that SDR would serve as a useful unit of account. Net receivers of SDRs over their allocation earn interest to be paid by the net users. The rate to be paid is determined in reference to the defined instruments of the five major currencies, which constitute the basket of valuation. Since its introduction a total of 21.4 billion SDRs were allocated over two three-year periods. Those happened in 1970-1972 and in 1979-1981. As of March 2000, the share of SDRs within nongold reserves remain at less than 1.3 percent (IMF, Annual Report, 2000). SDR and the Development Finance Link One main feature of Keynes's bancor proposal attracted special attention because it reached another domain, development. The grant of overdraft facilities initially aimed at providing postwar relief, rehabilitation, and reconstruction by allowing the international body of ICU to help by distributing unused funds. Williamson (1977) traces the origins of discussion, instituting a link between SDR allocations and development finance to Keynes's proposal. He observed that there were subsequent proposals also offering mechanisms for development borrowing. Most proposals prior to 1970 suggested the link be established in the form of project aid by the Development Finance Institutions (DFI). The majority of Less-Developed Countries (LDCs) clearly had interest in a quota-based system of distribution with special provisions for the least developed, since borrowing from International Development Agencies (IDA) was concentrated to a limited number of LDCs (Williamson 1977). During the Committee of Twenty negotiations of 1972-1974, LDCs exhibited a common position, using a weighting factor that is greater than one to determine the entitlement to SDR allocations over quotas (Williamson 1977, p.83). However, Williamson additionally commented that a quota-based allocation would be less progressive than distribution through IDA to the poorest countries, because quotas are determined in proportion to economic wealth of individual countries. After identifying the United States and Germany as the only two industrialized countries petitioning against the link, Williamson finished his article on a rather pessimistic note. He advised the developing countries to find some means of exploiting the existent nonsystem. Kafka (1977) commented on Williamson's article. He disagreed with Williamson on the potential of a link. The link would be most useful for making aid available, in spite of imperfect capital markets. Kafka urges the LDCs to insist on a large quota increase for all countries. He argues that even if aid comes in the form of balance of payments finance (rather than development), it would still feed into and help development progress. In conclusion, both the quantitative and qualitative aspects of SDR leave it as supplemental to existing forms of world money (Guttmann 1994, p.395). Solomon points at the efforts of the U.S (during negotiations) that propose not introducing the new reserve asset as a new unit, therefore not appearing as a rival for the dollar (1996). Solomon also argues that the stress on international liquidity during the 1960s was overdone. He claims that the balance of payment adjustment process deserves more attention than the international liquidity issues. Fischer believes market developments in connection with increasing capital mobility will diminish the asymmetry involved in the status of reserve centers (1983). Contrarily, Williamson points to the reserve shortfall in many developing countries, mostly consequential from troubles of inaccessibilty to borrow under favorable terms. Furthermore, borrowed reserves evaporate at times when most needed (as the 1982 debt crisis demonstrated (1984, p.24)). As a side note, Williamson's position appears to have shifted to being more optimistic about the potential of SDR from 1977 to 1984. Fischer (1983) discusses the future of SDR in relation to the possibility of the IMF changing into a World Central Bank. He notes that the size of the IMF's portfolio, and the process of negotiation that must precede any SDR-stock increase, prevent IMF to act as a lender of last resort. According to him, stabilizing trade cycles is the second main function of a central bank. He argues that it can be enhanced by increasing use of SDRs as a reserve asset and also, particularly, by increasing private institution SDR use. 3.3 Guttmann's SNCM Proposal Guttmann's (1994) proposal represents more of a recent attempt considering an arrangement with an International Monetary Authority (IMA) playing a central role, and a SupraNational Credit Money (SNCM) instituted in a multilateral regulation system. In reference to the Bancor proposal, Guttmann notes that Bancor would serve as an official means of debt settlement (Guttmann 1994, p.428) and would have required extensive controls on private cross-border capital flows. As for the SDR and European Currency Unit (ECU), he posits a similar argument. They have been primarily used as official reserve and debt-settlement devices. He contends (on the same issue as Fischer) that their private use is extremely limited and that impedes their ability to compete with other forms of international money. Further, he adds that the method of valuation for them as currency baskets impairs their ability to function effectively; either as an international measure of value, or anchor for stable currency prices. Since Guttmann wrote these lines, only one criticism has changed: the Euro was introduced for widespread private use in January 2002. The European Union presents three characteristics favoring one-money form as being much more practical in business. Those attributes are the volume of intra-EC trade, emergence of a single regional market, and unrestricted cross-movements of capital (Guttmann 1994, p.429). When considering the world, Guttmann argues that the propensity for uneven development is the precise reason for shaping the emerging global accumulation regime through an institutional policy framework that fosters integration and balance. Hence, the development link occupies the central reasoning in Guttmann's proposal. Guttmann maintains that use of national credit money as world money is an inherently unstable arrangement. When used for international transactions, national currencies fail to properly perform the medium of payment and unit of account functions. Issuing countries are allowed to meet their international obligations by simply printing their own money, thwarting the first of these two functions. Having their values defined in reference to other currencies, whose values are defined in reference to them, indicates that the system is without a proper valuation standard. The inadequacies of this money form are observed to feed chronic external imbalances, volatile exchange rates, massive speculation, and an unstable global banking network outside the reach of government regulators. These institutional deficiencies contributed to leaving countries at the periphery without adequate access to capital and markets (Guttmann 1994, p.428). Furthermore, choices of trading partners are also influenced by the currency used for payment. This fact favors nations with currencies in widespread use. Therefore it limits trading options, especially for less-developed countries. In early progression of his idea, Guttmann differentiates between commodity money and credit money (Guttmann 1994, p.29). He asserts that exogeneity and neutrality hold only for a commodity money. In reality, on the other hand, we use credit money where monetary payments involve triangular transactions including buyer, seller and bank. Money creation is tied to bank lending, where they assume a role greater than just being intermediaries. As for institutional deficiencies of the multicurrency system, Guttmann notes that it is difficult to manage, because it leaves discretion entirely on the policy-makers of the leading economic powers. Coordination of their decisions is hard to achieve, due mostly to conflicting national interests (Guttmann 1994, p.428). In reference to the globally integrated production networks and financial markets, Guttmann argues that the time has come for a truly international medium of exchange. That seems the next logical step in historic evolution of the international monetary system. As for the SNCM, Guttmann seeks its proper integration with national currencies as their international extension, as it is supposed to serve as money in all international transactions. This arrangement covers all foreign transactions as performed through the Central Bank accounts at IMA. He points out that constituting an important aspect, differentiating it from Bancor, SDR, and ECU. Those are associated with a more limited role, only functioning as an international means of payment to settle net official debit balances. That is to say, Guttmann suggests SNCM not only as a reserve asset, but also as an international currency for all international transactions. IMA's clearing facilities are organized in a similar fashion to Keynes's Bancor proposal, channeling the surplus funds to deficit spending. As for the advantages of such an arrangement, for surplus countries there is a reduction of risk exposure by lending to the IMA (rather than directly to deficit countries), and for debtor nations it provides a more reliable source of funds than the global banking system or industrial nation governments. To make sure that deficit countries will repay their debt, IMA could link credit extension to adoption of specific policies. Differences from current IMF practices would be to have these policies introduced more gradually, and regulation of adjustment on the basis of automatic and nondiscriminatory rules. This arrangement is promising symmetry in the adjustment process, and institutionalizes the adjustment process under supervision of a neutral nonmarket agency: IMA. As noted above, the development link is a prime motive for this SNCM proposal. This plan explicitly favors developing countries, while rich nations are thought to benefit rather indirectly through increased export markets, reduced illegal immigration, and greater supplies of cheap labor. This new picture would correspond to a new international division of labor. In the process of capital transfers to poorer countries, IMA is described to combine the roles of IMF and the World Bank on a much larger scale (Guttmann 1994, p.441). These IMA loans are targeted for financing infrastructure investments, to increase the productive capacity and therefore be self-liquidating. On the positive side, IMA would be an agency freed from the private profit constraint of banks. This should allow for flexible adjustment of credit terms more to fit needs of the borrower. As for the creditor nations, lending to IMA provides a more secure arrangement than the current unregulated offshore banking deposits. Additionally, having an international scheme controlling the total borrowing of each country would avoid overextension of credit and possibly prevent following crisis situations. The impact of IMA's investment banking activity is bound to stimulate the world economy, as it adds to the purchasing power of developing countries. Exchange rates between national currencies and SNCM are supposed to reflect the purchasing power differences. These exchange rates are fixed, but subject to future modifications like chronic deficits leading to devaluation. As such, exchange rates are needed to fit in a picture with individual countries' trade accounts are essentially balanced while allowing less developed countries to run deficits. So Guttmann's proposal also includes a fixed exchange rate regime with possible future modifications, as was the case with the Keynes and Davidson plans (introduced earlier in this chapter). The presented plan is an intermediate stage toward a world with a single currency for all (Guttmann 1994, p.445). For that purpose it seeks: (i) abolishing direct exchange of currencies, (ii) denationalizing the creation of international liquidity, (iii) pushing transnational banks into a payment system run by an IMA, (iv) fostering gradual correction of disequilibria while reconfiguring the distribution of adjustment burdens among countries, (v) enforcing on national governments greater coordination of macro policies, (vi) assuring greater access to capital for developing countries. CHAPTER 4 COUNTERARGUMENTS AGAINST WORLD CURRENCY PROPOSALS Proposals for fundamentally reforming the international monetary system attracted significant opposition on varied grounds. Some counterarguments address the economic features of the proposed changes, while others make reference to political aspects. One core issue raises significant concern over the possibility of switching to a world money system. That subject is the exchange rate regime that would be set as an adjustable fixed-exchange-rate system, as opposed to the (now dominant) managed floating. This issue is at the core; one of the prime motives for proposing a world currency lies in dissatisfaction with widespread floating exchange rates and impact of associated uncertainties. Fischer (1983) thinks that relatively closed economies should maintain flexible exchange rates with the rest of the world, under the presumption price and wage stickiness exist within each country or region. Nevertheless, the debate over exchange rate regimes is far more elaborate than what can be summarized in a short paragraph, and was partially covered in the second chapter. Most of the other criticisms on the economic analysis side primarily focus on three issues: loss of seigniorage to nations' accounts, ceasing the option of using inflation tax, and taking away monetary policy decisions from national authorities to grant them unto an international agency. By changing to a world currency system, income generated from currency issuance would accrue to the World Central Bank (WCB) at the first instance of money creation. Fischer (1982) indicates that in some years, various countries earned more than 5 percent of their GNP from seigniorage. Accordingly, he concludes that the basis for allocation of seigniorage would be crucial for successful WCB creation. Another argument on the same issue is brought up by Jefferson (1998) as he calculates the seigniorage income to the United States and indicates a trend: contribution of the rest-of-the world has surpassed the domestic contribution since the early 1990s. Sinn and Feist (1997) analyze the case with the European Monetary Union. According to the Maastricht treaty, each country's share of seigniorage is designated proportional to their equity shares of the European Central Bank (ECB). Equity shares are, in turn, derived from the population and GDP figures of individual countries. Consequently, countries with relatively low current monetary bases are emerging as beneficiaries from the switch to the Euro. For the possibility of a world currency, it is again apparent that formula negotiations for seigniorage distribution will include more than just population, GDP figures, and preceding national monetary bases. Countries with current key currencies would especially be seeking to protect the advantage they have. However, the ultimate purpose of these plans include the introduction of rather symmetric features to the international monetary system. Another concern is the loss of inflation tax as an independent instrument of national policy. Fischer sees this as the main fiscal consequence of creating WCB (1983, p.184). A switch to world currency would remove this source of emergency revenue. One might think the governments could use explicit taxation in place of inflation tax. However, such a switch would also possibly face political obstacles. As a stylized fact, governments do not show enthusiastic support for a world money idea, and their reasoning includes the ability to run independent monetary policy. Additionally, at the transitional stage, due to commitment of maintaining convertibility of fixed exchange rates, countries would be forced to adjust their monetary policies - on the basis of their world money reserves. Smithin and Wolf (1999) point to two key issues favoring independent national policy making. The first one relates to democratic accountability that is aligning responsibility for economic decision making directly with political arrangements. Secondly, they attribute a deflationary bias to practicing international bureaucracies. Gunter (1996), on the other hand, argues such independence of national policies is already lost to a great extent. The interconnectedness among countries in production, trade, and other international affairs modify and restrict available options. Smithin and Wolf also discuss if monetary sovereignty is even feasible in the contemporary global economy (1999, p.221). They conclude that structural changes in world economy necessitate a new set of principles for monetary policy in the new environment. The need for foreign exchange reserves of individual countries already exists within the current system. Despite the initial expectation that floating exchange rates would eliminate the need for holding reserves, national central banks do so partly in recognition of possible speculative attacks targeting exchange rates, alongside regular payment obligations. Another concern is that a world money would make control of capital movements more difficult (Fischer 1983). This might be true at the last stage of this conversion, when public widespread world money usage is established. However, as the currently studied proposals stand, a much more centralized exchange of funds would be the case. Therefore they propose what appears to be a scheme; where it will be possible to watch the flow of capital both at the overall and individual transaction levels. Even though exchange rate fluctuations will no longer be a source of distress, other financial and trade policy difficulties may get worse. Fischer thinks that other weapons such as import restrictions, tariffs, and commercial policy would likely develop as an alternative means of adjustment. Opposing this, life without exchange rate adjustments may trigger a more extensive cooperation among countries. Competitive or cooperative mood domination is a question of whether countries demonstrate willingness to adjust their policies. European countries have been trying to accomplish this over time with their agricultural policy disputes. Another issue makes reference to the public good nature of the basic benefit of such a new system. In very broad terms, governments would have to give up seigniorage and countercyclical monetary policy in exchange for a smoother running international financial and monetary system. This reward is difficult to share - in a way that would make all governments better off. This objection primarily arises in reference to inability to quantify and control benefit distribution in the new proposed system. Meanwhile, qualitative assessments accompanied with quantitative indicators are valid criteria to judge the success or displeasure with a world currency system. As Keynes noted, individual countries would need the choice of leaving the scheme at due notice, as they decide. Fischer coined the phrase `world money exchange standard,' describing when each country is obliged to clear all balances against other countries through their central bank accounts at the WCB. Against Guttmann's claim, Fischer thinks such structure would limit the world money's function to being only a reserve asset. Guttmann argued that his SNCM would achieve widespread use by including all transactions of current and capital accounts, unlike the earlier examples of SDR and Bancor. As a result, SNCM's role (he thought) would reach beyond being just a reserve asset. Rather than leaving the argument a claim, Guttmann could have proposed policies to promote other functions of money to be acquired by SNCM. The proposal would have then held more of a real application point of view. In this world money exchange standard, if world money is held privately, as well as by public sector, then world money turns into a fiat asset whose value derives purely from acceptability in exchange. Fischer argues that the main difficulty with world money exchange standard is the maintenance of parities. Davidson's plan had a provision aiming at this issue. He suggested a one-way convertibility arrangement, leaving discretion to WCB for demanding national currencies for world money. This would allow WCB to obtain national currencies when trying to maintain parities. If private agents are allowed to hold world money, WCB could accomplish such a move by selling securities in any national market where monetary growth is observed as excessive. This would mean, essentially, each government gives the WCB power to undo national monetary policies during (at least) the transitional stage to a single currency regime. In connection to this point, Fischer thinks a world money exchange system would be neither credible nor workable as a fixed parity system. Fischer argues that if the inflation rate of world money happens to be high, it is likely to see private currencies being issued. Those currences would be convertible to world money, but pay a rate of return indexed to a price level. Such possibility suggests that it would be undesirable to outlaw private currency for the possibility of issue, providing a behavior check on the WCB (Fischer 1983, p.182). One line of counterarguments reference the Optimum Currency Areas literature. In the early 1960s, Mundell (1961) and McKinnon (1963) introduced the concept of Optimum Currency Areas (OCA). It was an attempt to consider the economic costs and benefits of establishing currency borders. Along these lines, it was argued that diversity among countries, in terms of their institutional features and economic situations, would be an obstacle for having a single currency serve them. It suggests that in the face of differential national shocks, macroeconomic instability will emerge due to limitations on exchange rate adjustment (Minford 2000, p.69). Fischer (1983) points to a weakness of the OCA analysis: its treatment of factor mobility is exogeneous. He counteracts, referring to the 1970s, when extent of trade and factor mobility proved intimately linked with the exchange rate arrangement. Since their impact would reach many different domains (challenging the status quo), it is no surprise to see many arguments advanced against SNCM proposals. These proposals address systemic features with intention to changing them in major ways. An assessment of the current problems would be the starting point for deciding if a new system is needed, and if so what features would bring a more satisfactory functioning of the system. If the choice emerges in favor of a common currency, a primary question stands; how to form a monetary union without having a political union. Is it possible to convince countries for undertaking such a fundamental cooperative endeavor given existing political structures? The next chapter presents an analysis of the political economy aspects of these proposals. CHAPTER 5 POLITICAL ECONOMY ASPECTS OF THE WORLD CURRENCY PROPOSALS In this chapter, first a general introduction to the political economy of international monetary relations will be presented. Next, issues involved in political economy of monetary unions will be discussed. Following, Keynes's Bancor proposal, SDR, and Guttmann's proposal will be examined in relation to the political economy aspects. Political economy is `...a vast terrain of research and analysis into economic systems evolving through historical time' (O'Hara 1999, p.867). It is different from neoclassical economics, which takes a general approach to the study of economy and society. The neoclassical approach relies mainly on individualistic explanations putting less emphasis on historical and social explanations. Political economy `...is characterized by the inclusion of historical and social context as part of the fundamental factors which shape and create economic activity' (Clark 1999, p.868). Hence, a political economy perspective opens the doors to a multitude of theories and approaches to explaining economic phenomena. Studying world money proposals with specific attention for political economy aspects will help us discover the social and historical context surrounding these proposals. 5.1 Political Economy of International Monetary Relations A fundamental difference of the international monetary system from the domestic monetary systems is the presence of separate national currencies. There is no existing formal world money, even though selected national currencies play important international roles. The right to create and manage money is seen as a cohesive part of the state sovereignty (Cohen 1993) since the nineteenth century. Recently, the connection between money and nation-states has been subjected to a variety of challenges. Many European countries seem to be voluntarily abandoning their national currencies in favor of a joint currency; almost all of the newly formed states in Europe and Central Asia adopted their own national currencies (Goodhart 1995, p.449). Challenges include the growth of offshore banking activities, currency substitution, emergence of local currencies, and the possibility of private electronic monies in the future (Gilbert and Helleiner 1999, p.1). The political economy of monetary relations is to be understood within the interdisciplinary field of international political economy. Two broad sets of questions reflect the focus of the studies in political economy of monetary relations. The first group of studies addresses the motivations behind government behavior in international monetary relations. The second group focuses more on managing consequences of monetary interdependence. An analysis of the system's performance, in the face of policy conflicts, is tackled by this latter group of studies (Cohen 1993, p.xi). This grouping reflects the nature of the question at hand, which requires a holistic approach to include the desire for sovereignty and de facto dependency among nations. In line with that recognition, elements of both cooperation and competition explain the monetary relations between sovereign states. Promotion of the highest level of technical efficiency and economic welfare calls for improved cooperation. On the other hand, the core of the competitive aspects is about the distribution of economic welfare and political power. At this point it is important to distinguish the terms competition and cooperation as used in political science and in economics. In economics, competition may be a form of cooperation for organizing economic activities. In political science, competition for power is the opposite of using cooperation to achieve common goals by sharing power. Political power relations considerably affect the conduct of monetary affairs between countries. Viner (1929) provides a detailed account of the connection between international loan transactions of European governments and their balance-of-power diplomacy from the 1880s into the First World War. There are striking stories of using financial measures, in line with shifting political alignments of creditor countries. Similar stories are quite easy to find currently, as well as throughout history. Political alliances, as part of power struggles between nations, have shaped monetary matters - as both conflicts and motive for cooperation. Cooper (1975) concurs that international monetary relations can be understood as incorporating both cooperative and competitive elements. Sources of conflict in the international monetary regime are important to investigate because of the resultant actions that govern conduct of individual country policies and economic outcomes. Cooper lists five general reasons for monetary issue controversy. Firstly, there would be diverging preferences about distributional implications. Secondly, conflicting preferences among policy objectives would lead to conflicts. Thirdly, distinct national economic circumstances would suggest disagreements. Fourthly, conflicts over means-ends relationships may emerge. Lastly, uncertainties about reliability of other countries would lead to disputes. Of these five, the first four make reference to mostly economic concerns. Meanwhile, the fifth is a rather political condition. Generally, most economic aspects are displayed at the forefront, while politics are often the key determinant on issues. There are a multitude of dimensions when delegations meet to discuss international monetary relations. Therefore, compromises at the negotiation table can be achieved only through a comprehensive evaluation covering many aspects. Hence, when it comes to reconciling differences between states there would be no unique solution. Accordingly, a variety of cooperation possibilities exist for both the top-level decisions (with regard to the regime choices) and for lower-level decisions (concerning daily activities). Bryant (1995) provides a systematic presentation of alternative arrangements regarding international cooperation between nations. He develops a classification involving several dimensions. The first of these dimensions corresponds to the numbers and strengths of international institutions and forums. The second dimension is identified as the extent of treaties, agreements, understandings and norms among individual national governments. These two dimensions locate a spectrum of regime choices, ranging from `national sovereignty with little or no cooperation' to `mutual governance through strong federal supranational institutions' (1995, p.395). Next, Bryant adds a third dimension: the amount of information exchange, consultations and bargaining in lower-level ongoing decision-making. Thereby, the lower-level ongoing cooperation is introduced into the classification to complement possibilities of international regime environments. Bryant adds one more dimension to this taxonomy, the degree of activism in national operating regimes. This presentation of possibilities allows for distinguishing characteristics of international cooperation among national governments, together with choices of activism for national operating regimes. The above categorization also helps to identify the relevance of contributions from three major perspectives in analysis of international cooperation. These three perspectives are rule analysis, policy optimization analysis, and institutionalist analysis. These different points of view provide a diverse outlook on international cooperation by their varying emphasis of possibilities. Each of these perspectives seems to enhance our understanding in different ways, since the focus of each on Bryant's categorization falls on somewhat distinct fields. Some attempts to explain relatively more stable periods in history make reference to the presence of a stabilizing hegemonic power for the whole system. Eichengreen (1989) considers the hegemonic stability theories in connection with three different epochs of the world's monetary history: classical gold standard, interwar years, and Bretton-Woods system. He concurs with Keohane's ``hegemonic cooperation'' notion: `...cooperation is required for systemic stability even in periods of hegemonic dominance, although the presence of a hegemon may encourage cooperative behavior' (Eichengreen, 1989, p.287). This conclusion points at the overlap between various aspects contributing to the explanation of stabilizing the regime. Eichengreen (1995) develops a general explanation while studying shifts between exchange-rate regimes. He advances six hypotheses to explain endogeneous factors responsible for shifts between fixed and flexible exchange-rate regimes: leadership, cooperation, intellectual consensus, behavior of the macroeconomy, fiscal and monetary rules, and distributional politics. These hypotheses are neither mutually exclusive nor incompatible, since there is considerable overlap among them. Accordingly, Eichengreen concludes that a discussion against the evidence should include a blending of these hypotheses. Furthermore, such an attempt can incorporate an analysis of external pressures for international cooperation alongside the primacy of domestic politics. Understanding the shift to alternative arrangements also requires an explanation of change in balance of regime costs and benefits. Endogeneous regime dynamics, together with the choice of regime, would present a more complete description. Progress of the European Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) provides concrete examples of different perspectives entertained by the participating and nonparticipating countries. Conflicting visions exist regarding the possibility of EMU success. Eichengreen indicates that empirical evidence is inconclusive regarding impact on economic welfare (1993, p.1353). Wyplosz (1997) argues in favor, referring both to political desire and economic benefits. Feldstein (1997), on the contrary, disbelieves in the success of this process. He argues that the political conflicts will deepen, together with the detrimental economic impacts of the EMU. Verdun (1999) contends that European monetary integration is a gradual process and represents the logical step forward. Discussions of international monetary systems seem to have accelerated with excitement of the European experience. In addition to insights to be gained from this experience, possible success would bring about significant consequences for world politics. Possible changes in hegemonic positions in the monetary realm would most probably find parallels, with respect to balance-of-power at the political scene of the world. Hence, watching for developments with EMU will be enlightening, not only for the possibility of an international monetary reform, but also for likely accompanying changes of power among countries. Even though EMU is an attempt at regional level monetary unification, troubles during implementation and possible success will provide hindsight for feasibility of global international money initiatives. As for world currency proposals, an inquiry into their political economy aspects would reveal political concerns, relevant in consideration of proposal viability. When we question the nature of international monetary arrangements, we delve into the realms of central banking. The extent of ability to control money supply by central banks is perceived differently by different schools of thought. Neoclassical theory attributes full control to central banks, while post-Keynesians point to the endogeneous factors determining money supply. Still, roles of central banks in monetary policy decisions and domestic or international finance undoubtedly place the utmost weight on institutional characteristics of central banks. Therefore, central banking is intrinsically political. When it comes to world currency proposals within the current political structure we need to ask: Is it possible to have a World Central Bank without having a world government? The concept of state sovereignty is seen directly connected with the sole right to create and manage money. Politics imply having each state with individualized exchange rates, with its balance of payments corresponding with policy priorities and objectives. A rich research agenda is still awaiting exploration, needed for understanding political implications of world currency proposals with regard to key political economy issues. In the next section, we turn to the question of political economy aspects of monetary unions, in general. Following, we investigate world currency proposals in these terms. 5.2 Political Economy of Monetary Unions Optimum Currency Areas (OCA) theory led to significant amounts of discussion on possible costs and benefits of currency unions (Mundell 1997; DeGrauwe 1996). However, when it comes to choices made in the real world, there are severe doubts about the predictive power of the OCA theory. It is observed that political processes are key determinants of answers for currency questions. The breakup of the Soviet Union and the formation of the EMU are recent examples of how political changes correspond to the emergence of new currencies, as opposed to eradication of independent national currencies in favor of joint currency, primarily as a political choice (Goodhart 1995, p.449) . Connections from currency issues to political concerns are maintained through multiple channels. These channels include economic benefits of monetary autonomy, the role of seigniorage, and the symbolic significance of national currencies as emblems of sovereignty. They are the most commonly discussed issues in this regard. Loss of monetary policy as a national instrument for demand management is seen as the primary cost of changing to a common currency. Monetary policy can be used for targeting interest rates or exchange rates. However, by itself, monetary policy cannot achieve differing objectives for both rates. Aiming at both targets would call for another instrument, like exchange controls to supplement monetary policy. The Maastricht Treaty assigned monetary policy operations to an independent European System of Central Banks (ESCB), while assigning external exchange-rate decisions to politicians (Goodhart 1995, p.457). This issue raised considerable concern. Apart from the question regarding the ability to control exchange rates, or nominal interest rates, in a discretionary fashion, politicians are especially suspected of pursuing personal political choices over public interest. Independence for central banks from the executive branch in a country is argued to be necessary if politicians lose credibility to commitments against inflation, resulting from attempts to engineer short-term output increases. This notion assigns the central bank with an overriding task of price stability. In line with this contention, the Maastricht Treaty adopted such a role for the European Central Bank (ECB). During transition to the monetary union in Europe, the Exchange Rate Mechanism constrained the use of monetary policies (over time) by member states. That means that a large part of cost (from abandoning monetary policy) was already experienced during that transitional stage to full monetary union. These issues of transition are examined further in subsection 5.2.3. Objections over loss of monetary autonomy can be seen as a representative issue for general concern over national interests. Monetary policy is discussed mainly while it may be a more general worry regarding protection for national interests what is raising doubts about change to common currency. Seigniorage from note issuing can be a significant source of revenue for countries. It would matter most in times of war and crises, when alternative sources of funds are difficult or impossible to extend. Security considerations form a significant reason for maintaining a national currency. This national--defense rationale indicates determination of the French and Germans to finish their rivalry and the series of European wars is a political key in the formation of EC and moving to a single currency (Goodhart 1995, p.455). There is also an attempt to explain the reliance on seigniorage through time inconsistency of civil authorities. Time inconsistency reasoning suggests a connection to political business cycles hypothesis, and also argues that instability of the national government would lead to using seigniorage extensively. Since currency is the most tangible and commonly used claim to goods and services, substantial significance is associated with its image and control (Goodhart 1995, p.454). Most of the time, a strong national currency provides grounds for national satisfaction while devaluation is seen as a sign of national weakness. This association contributes to the perception of national currency as a national symbol. Monetary autonomy, seigniorage, and symbolic significance of national currencies represent the central themes of objections against monetary unification. They each refer to considerations that could easily spark political confrontations. Meanwhile, economic benefits and costs are thrown to the forefront in many analyses and discussions - more so than political aspects. Next, we will look at economic costs and benefits of monetary unification. 5.2.1 Economic Benefits and Costs First, let us turn to the benefits to come out of monetary unification in the long run, at the steady-state after transition is complete. Goodhart notes that most economic gains from monetary union would come in increased microeconomic efficiency (1995, p.458). Benefits include a reduction in transactions costs. Smaller countries and companies are likely to benefit more from these savings in comparison to larger ones, since larger companies and countries usually pay comparatively smaller transactions costs. Secondly, there would be reduced risk in realignment and devaluation. Risk premia on national real interest rates are thought to reflect expectations of business leaders; on possibility of realignment in exchange rates. Reduction in risk premium is estimated to bring significant increases in community income for the European Union (Goodhart 1995, p.459). Thirdly, there would be efficiency gains to trade and capital movements. The impact of decreasing exchange rate uncertainty and greater price transparency are difficult to quantify. Yet the scale of the markets would be expected to expand as a result of reduction in exchange rate variability and improved price transparency. Fourthly, monetary unification is likely to bring an internationally stronger currency. Relative position of the union in international negotiations would be enhanced, providing heightened authority. Fifthly, monetary unification is thought to lead to more stable prices. Goodhart (1995) casts doubt on whether possible emergence of price stability should be attributed to the independence of ECB or to EMU (as a system). Abbott (2000) also challenges independence arguments for central banks. She refers to the strength of the economy leading to low inflation rates rather than structure of central bank governance. This is considering the countries presented as examples of independence for central bank yielding low inflation rates. In addition to microeconomic gains, there are two other main arguments favoring monetary unification. As European integration suggests, it may be necessary to have a single currency for single market success. It may also be a prerequisite for further fiscal federalism. These two issues will be further elaborated on in the next subsection. The main economic cost of joining a monetary union is identified as the loss of domestic monetary policy as an instrument of national demand management. Goodhart argues the extent of this cost will depend on: (1) Extent of likely asymmetric shocks to participating nations and regions, (2) Wage flexibility and possibility of migration of factors of production to indicating the speed and flexibility in relation to adjusting disequilibria, (3) How far can the fiscal policy be used as an alternative to monetary policy adjustments (1995, p.461). The first two of these three conditions resemble initial criteria of the OCA theory, as introduced by Mundell, McKinnon, and Kenen. Considering the European Union, Goodhart indicates that core countries are noted to have converged sufficiently for monetary union feasibility. The Commission of European Communities (1990) report argues that asymmetric shocks are likely to fade when trade barriers are eliminated. The peripheral countries are thought to benefit more from EMU advantages, reductions in transaction costs, risk premia and improved price stability. Against this argument (in reference to the American experience), it is argued that local economies will become more dissimilar; making themselves subject to asymmetric shocks (Goodhart 1995, p.462). There have been studies on nominal and real-wage rigidities in European Community (EC) countries. Generally, the findings are that EC countries demonstrate considerable real-wage rigidities, together with little nominal-wage rigidities, while the United States is found to have more nominal-wage rigidities alongside much less real-wage rigidities. It is possible to use this result in both support of or against EMU. Existence of real-wage rigidities would imply that improving competitiveness through nominal devaluations is not as possible, and EMU will not show a big resultant loss for this aspect. On the other hand, the same finding would indicate that labor markets will probably have a harder time adjusting to regional disequilibria. Nevertheless, there are additional arguments (with regards to both) on the existence of real exchange rate adjustments before EMU, and likely changes in labor markets after EMU. It is quite possible to attribute these differences in labor markets as stemming from the strength of labor movement at varying degrees, in different countries. The resultant labor market structures also affect fiscal expenditure patterns. There is a serious trouble for empirical work in questioning whether or not the monetary union will bring convergence. Since most single currency domains overlap with political and fiscal domains, any observed convergence would be hard to attribute to the role of the monetary union. We will consider interactions between the currency, fiscal, and trade domains in the next subsection. 5.2.2 Currency Domain in relation to Fiscal and Trade Domains There are many unanswered fundamental questions regarding the case of a single currency with respect to fiscal and trade domains. In this section, we will investigate the answers in mostly general terms, but still with references to European experience. 5.2.2.1 Does a single currency scheme require fiscal federalism? Fiscal measures would provide an alternative mechanism of demand management when separate currencies are abandoned, corresponding to individual state losses of control on monetary policy. These fiscal measures would aim at both stabilization and redistribution. Stabilization efforts would be associated with asymmetric shocks, while redistribution policies are emphasized more in cases of regional divergence (Goodhart 1995, p.466). One argument in favor of shifting fiscal functions to a federal center refers to fiscal constraints designed against budgetary indiscipline. The European Union Maastricht Treaty's requirements on national governments' deficits and debts signify an attempt to bring restraints on national authorities. Such limits leave a relatively smaller scope for national stabilization efforts. Instead, transferring fiscal function to the federal level would provide room for stabilization policies. An additional argument, in favor of centralizing fiscal functions, makes note of the overspills into neighboring areas. A country with a high marginal propensity to import may pursue less than desirable fiscal activities. Authorities of that country might consider that benefits of an expansionary fiscal policy would mainly accrue to other countries. On the other hand, the impact of excessive government deficits on national interest rates would be partly reduced with an increase of the general level of EC interest rates. When domestic interest rates start to increase, a search for lower interest rates outside of the country would increase EC interest rates to some extent. A less disciplined behavior may be observed as part of national fiscal policymakers, in relation to overspills of national fiscal policies. Another argument in favor of centralizing fiscal functions relates to increased factor mobility. Movements of production factors, in response to differential tax rates, make it difficult to distinguish national benefits of said taxes. That is to say, increased factor mobility would enforce a convergence of tax rates. Goodhart, in reference to the studies of existing federal states, concludes both stabilization and redistribution functions have been actively carried out by those federal fiscal systems (1995, p.469). However, he believes a transfer of unconditional redistributive functions to Brussels is unlikely. Some opposition to further transferring fiscal power to Brussels is discussed on political grounds. It is argued that the likelihood of substantial asymmetric shocks and the benefits resulting from a federal insurance scheme are both small. Furthermore, moral hazard and situations when a nation is seen at fault would present risks for the ability of a federal insurance scheme to function. One more argument in favor of federal stabilization is again in political terms. Cyclical downturns would be handled much more easily, helping defense of the monetary union if temporarily disadvantaged countries were to be helped through federal fiscal transfers. 5.2.2.2 Is a single currency needed to support fiscal federalism? Feldstein (1992) argues that successful functioning of a monetary union would rely on interrelations of monetary policy, and fiscal and trade policies. Meanwhile, Goodhart asserts that it might be possible to operate EMU while leaving most stabilization and redistribution functions at a national level. It is possible to argue for a causal connection between comparatively fixed exchange rates and success of a centralized fiscal domain. As an example, Common Agricultural Policy agreements are able to function only if intracommunity exchange rates remain stable (Goodhart 1995, p.472). Hence, moving toward a single market appears possible in connection with perceived success of exchange rate stabilization arrangements. There are reasons for doubt about the consistency of a regime with periodic exchange-rate adjustments and transfer of a considerable part of fiscal responsibility to a federal center. Existence of separate national currencies facilitates discussion of EC fiscal policies on the basis of state identification. In contrast, a single currency would shift focus of debate to group identification with respect to characteristics including age, job, and income rather than geographic location. Discussion of policy impacts on different groups would be likely. Goodhart indicates discussion in national terms represents a centrifugal force, while discussion in terms of groups irrespective of location would serve as a centripetal force (1995, p.474). When fiscal expenditures are financed by taxes, knowing some regions would benefit would make achievement of agreement between regions difficult. Martin (1993) argues that cohesion is maintained by international organizations (like EC) by facilitating stable linkages among issues. Keohane (1984) concurs, saying that in world politics, international regimes help to arrange linkage of issues, and thereby surface side-payments. Cohen (1993) contends that success of currency integration will depend on the existence of `...either a local hegemon or a fabric of related ties with sufficient influence to neutralize the risk of time inconsistency' (quoted in Goodhart 1995, p.474). In this regard, adoption of a single currency is seen as a potential means of strengthening ties. Cohen indicates that the process is mutually interactive between formation of currency union and federalism in the fiscal sphere, as well as encouraging ties in other spheres. There is some opposition against and fear of EMU; it being an important step to federal Europe, where identity and power of nation-states would be reduced. For these opponents, the agenda of federalism is hard to accept, rather than considerations of benefits to and costs of a monetary union. Political sovereignty is the focal point of these prejudices. Meanwhile, other groups consider that in order to survive a monetary union must be accompanied with greater fiscal and political federalism. They worry that local politicians would blame federal constraints for a future national depression. The dispute between these two groups focuses on whether a monetary union requires fiscal and political powers to be transferred to a federal center, or if a monetary union can precede such large-scale transfer of power. Respectively, Goodhart associates these two positions with German coronation theorists and monetarists. Opposing stands introduced (above) reflect divergent opinions on the implementation of a transition. Germans asserted the convergence of macroeconomic policies and performances, and that transfer of power to the center should precede the monetary union. The French argued for immediate abolition of fluctuation bands and transition to permanently fixed exchange rates (Goodhart 1995, p.475). This conflict made the Commission (1990) embrace the principle of subsidiarity as a compromise. This principle asserts that policies should be decided at the lowest effective level of government. Such a statement takes argument from general to particular. Goodhart states, `For the time being, general questions about the relation between monetary union and the appropriate extent of federalism are purposefully masked as being both too difficult and too potentially inflammatory to attempt to answer directly.' (1995, p.476) As the European experience exemplifies, when there is political will compromises and deliberate efforts for covering troubling issues to leave them for future negotiations are applied. 5.2.2.3 Interactions between currency regimes and trade policies Goodhart points out that it is a threat to the success of a single market if exchange rates could be shifted independently from the desires and welfare of other members (1995, p.478). Further pegged (but adjustable) exchange rates are fragile in the face of political unwillingness to promptly realign. The only way to ensure success of the single market may be to move to EMU quickly. On the other hand, NAFTA operates with flexible exchange rates. Goodhart points to the hegemon role of the United States in NAFTA, while no such hegemon exists in the EC. Another difference of NAFTA and EC is the policies and rules adopted by monetary authorities. Canadian and Mexican central banks are observed to focus on price stability, rather than watching over national competitiveness. European authorities are noted to be relatively reluctant to accept constraints for conduct of monetary policy (1995, p.481). 5.2.3 The Transition to Monetary Union Many of the studies and plans for EMU presumed a series of stages in moving towards a monetary union. Accordingly, for EMS, there was first the Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) - with frequent realignments (1979 to 1983) that progressed with occasional realignments (1983 to 1987), and later with virtually fixed rates (1987 to 1992). The system was then to move (in 1994) to narrow bands for all EMS countries, permanently fixing the parities by 1999, and subsequently a single currency. This phased plan presents a number of advantages. In addition to making each step less radical, such a plan enabled supporters to compare economic and political advantages of monetary union to the ERM middle stage, where most economic costs are already incurred with few economic advantages (Goodhart 1995, p.482). Thus, advocates of monetary union argue that the main cost (loss of monetary sovereignty) has already been experienced in early stages of ERM. Benefits to peripheral countries would accrue at the final stage, when inflation-risk premia on interest rates would end and monetary policy would be set on an EMS-centered (replacing German-centered) basis. Goodhart finds this argument convincing within context of assumptions, but indicates some weaknesses. Firstly, none of the above arguments holds true for Germany. Transfer of power to ESCB would mean a potentially serious loss to Germany in terms of monetary sovereignty. It is worth investigating the German response to EMU. First, the Bundesbank is noted to be a main center of Euroskepticism (Goodhart 1995, p.482). Secondly, the bank, and most Germans insisted that no serious losses would be imposed on Germany through transfer of power to ESCB. This led to drafting the constitution of ESCB similar to (and even more rigid than) that of the Bundesbank. Independence, priority on price stability, and the absence of significant responsibility for banking system stability are some aspects instituted for ESCB through its constitution. Furthermore, they favored strict criteria to be established so that other countries could join ESCB only when their economic indicators converge with Germany. Benefits Germans see coming with EMU are also worth noting. They are essentially political, and aim at avoiding political and economic adversities in the last two centuries by transferring economic and political powers to a federal center (Goodhart 1995, p.483). In addition to this, Germany is observed to benefit from the single market, and its expansion toward the east, more than other members. To the extent that success of monetary union forms a condition to the success of the single market, Germany has stimulation for its EMU support. As an alternative to the currently pursued phased transition to a single currency, some plans argued for achieving economic convergence, while floating exchange rates are still in effect by granting national central banks independence and coordination to attain price stability during transition. A sudden transition to a single currency is envisioned, following convergence in economic indicators. The major counterargument is the experience with flexible exchange rates. Since 1973, exchange rates were not exclusively, or even primarily, determined by economic fundamentals and monetary policies. Hence, there is no guarantee to reach relatively stable or properly aligned exchange rates while maintaining flexible exchange rates (Goodhart 1995, p.484). Any sudden move to a monetary union could cause large capital gains and losses to borrowers and lenders. These proposals for keeping flexible exchange rates until the hour of unification primarily attempt to avoid fragility of exchange rates against speculative attacks during the intermediate period (as the 1992 crisis exhibited). Apart from the design of intermediate stages for transition, transitional costs of changing from one currency to another may be significant. These costs include disturbances to information sets of the public, establishing a new central bank, and printing new notes. Kenen (1992) identifies a list of six requirements to be met before the introduction of a single currency: having balance sheets of national central banks denominated in European Currency Units (ECU), credit institutions able to hold ECU balances with their central banks, an ECB funds market allowing credit institutions to lend to each other, government endorsement of marketable obligations guaranteeing to redeem in ECUs, a unified market for all securities with ECU endorsements so that interest rates of individual issues will be comparable, and that firms and individuals hold and deal with securities in ECU denominations. Monticelli and Vinals (1993) point out some conditions for achieving same-day payments and settlements of ECU balances. Common technical standards on operational reliability of central bank practices would be a prerequisite. In addition, safety measures would be required to reduce liquidity, credit, and systemic risks (Goodhart 1995, p.493). What considerations that normally make nations want to have separate currencies may now induce EC countries to voluntarily move toward a single currency? First is the connection between autonomous currencies and international constraints on the flows of goods, capital and other production factors. A second consideration is the form and nature of relations between monetary and fiscal policies. Whether or not it is sensible to push monetary union far ahead of fiscal and political union stands as the most crucial question. 5.3 Political Economy Aspects of the World Currency Proposals In this section we consider the three world currency proposals that were introduced in Chapter 3. The focus will be issues introduced in the previous section, and the extent these three proposals addressed the political economy. 5.3.1 Keynes's Bancor Proposal Keynes's proposal, in general terms, is an attempt to promote cooperation in spite of (then) acute conflicts. The recent experience of the Great Depression and the ongoing Second World War marked how disorderly world economy and politics were. Even though Keynes's plan essentially aimed at economic life, particularly the monetary sphere, it may be observed as a political agenda of a cooperation-oriented new order. Conflicts of those times most probably included all of Cooper's (1975) categories. Yet Keynes's proposal, as well as the Bretton Woods negotiations as a whole, represented an effort to reverse the trend of conflicts. If locating Keynes's proposal in Bryant's (1995) cooperation possibilities, it would possibly correspond to `strong activist coordination.' This identification has two defining aspects. With regard to the characteristics of interactions among national governments and international institutions, extensive joint decision-making is monitored and catalyzed by strong international institutions. The second aspect is the amount of information exchange, consultations and bargaining in ongoing lower-level decision-making. On this front, Keynes's proposal involves frequent consultations with active searches for mutually advantageous bargaining, which fit the `strong activist coordination' identification. As previously noted, political concerns seem to address three issues as the primary worries for a possible monetary union: economic benefits of monetary autonomy, the role of seigniorage, and symbolic significance of national currencies. Keynes's proposal envisions a system maintaining present national currencies. In part, this feature relieves strain of symbolic significance (the last of the above issues). In consideration of the other two issues, one important attribute of the Bancor plan is the establishment of fixed exchange rates. These rates are thought to be subject to rare adjustments, as conditions impose. However, this exchange rate arrangement would raise questions relating to monetary autonomy and seigniorage. Considering the period preceding the Bretton Woods negotiations, the Great Depression witnessed periods of unilateral action leading to disorder and consequential limitations on monetary autonomy. The Second World War again presented limited monetary autonomy, but with an extended role for seigniorage to support the war effort in many countries. Hence, opposition (especially to seigniorage) could be expected as severe. This prospect is still correlated with the vision of individual countries' willingness to accept an arrangement that would systematically work against the possible future war. The primary economic cost of monetary unification is seen to be the loss of monetary policy as a demand management tool. The extent of this cost to national economies would depend on the likelihood of asymmetric shocks to participating regions, flexibility of production factors adjusting to disequilibria, and ability to use fiscal measures for adjustments. Keynes's plan does not specifically address these issues, but rather leaves the plan with a limited scope. In fact, the plan intends to primarily restructure the international monetary system. The variety of issues involved at that level are more than enough to cause a stir at the discussion table. All that is included is a new way of handling international monetary affairs without interfering (much) with internal political structures of participant countries. This attribute was listed as a condition that Keynes thought necessary in order to make an International Monetary System sustainable. He noted that the technique of the plan should be applicable to prospective member states, irrespective of existing government and economic policy. These objections, as well as likely benefits, would be subject to investigation as part of individual country assessments when it comes to joining the scheme. Keynes discusses economic benefits of his plan almost exclusively in the macroeconomic realm. These benefits were introduced in Chapter 3, in reference to Keynes's (1943) presentation to the British Parliament. He listed the advantages of the plan in that document as part of the plan promotion. These benefits included expansionist pressure on world trade, overdraft mechanism (providing a means of multilateral credit facilities), and settling some rules to counter balance of payments disequilibria while shifting part of the responsibility to creditor nations. As observed, Keynes's promotion includes benefits that are all macroeconomic in nature. When we discussed economic benefits of monetary unification in the previous section, they were noted to be mostly microeconomic efficiency gains. Namely those are reduction in transactions costs, reducing the risk of realigning exchange rates, efficiency gains to trade and capital movements out of decreased exchange rate uncertainty and greater price transparency, more stable prices, and internationally stronger currency. With Keynes's plan, even though world money is not proposed to circulate freely in hands of private agents, almost all above listed microeconomic efficiency gains are still attainable. The exchange rate arrangement is the key for achieving efficiency gains to trade and capital movements, reducing risk of realigning exchange rates. As Wray (1999) pointed out, exchange rate stability is the feature facilitating expansionist world economy in Keynes's and Davidson's plans. Even though both Keynes and Davidson put the emphasis on macroeconomic aspects, at least some microeconomic benefits would accrue - without seeking a complete monetary unification. The proposed structure of ICU indicates a bias favoring smaller countries and Less Developed Countries (LDCs). Special emphasis is put on partly relieving the burden of balance of payments adjustment from debtor to creditor countries. There exist measures against continuing balance of payments disequilibrium. These measures apply to all participant countries on equal terms and promote egalitarian treatment towards participant countries. Furthermore, the proposal stipulates granting no veto power to any country or group of countries in ICU management. Additionally, overdraft facilities are designed to help countries with limited access to funds to initiate a recovery. Another issue regarding the proposal is the empowerment of ICU. For this purpose, the first step is envisioned as establishing rules to apply beforehand, and expecting national governments to decide on joining or not joining, according to those set terms. After that, the decision for participation is tying and ICU has authority to apply the rules as designed. While provisions are made to accommodate special circumstances, application of the agreed-upon-rules is not subject to any dispute between ICU management and national governments. Making requirements clear from the beginning while leaving the door open for quitting the scheme establishes ICU as an international body, with an enforceable framework over participant states. An additional component of empowerment for ICU is the one-way convertibility. Keynes sought to put ICU in a position where parity between Bancors and gold would not be threatened by member country demands for gold. Davidson included a similar feature in his plan, ensuring ICU would acquire national currencies as need be. Through these provisions, ICU is granted a status and ability in this respect: to watch system stability free from threat of unilateral actions by national governments and private speculators. A third aspect of Keynes's proposal demands attention. He proposed the governing board of ICU be composed of finance ministers of representative states. This would be a wise choice for gaining political support of national governments. The U.S. proposal, on the other hand, insisted on employing lower-level technical personnel on the board. The U.S. view claimed that subject matter of international finance is more of a technical exercise. The resultant structure, again, favored the U.S. position and kept the board as a group of technical experts. With Keynes's proposal, IMF's role would acquire a more widespread impact. The participants of the governing board (finance ministers) would have the capacity to go to their countries and defend decisions, against possible domestic opposition. 5.3.2 Special Drawing Rights Like Keynes's Bancor proposal, creation of SDR within the IMF structure is an attempt at promoting cooperation and addressing common problems in the world's monetary system. As discussed in the third chapter, the intellectual background leading to SDR included three major concerns during the 1960s: the possibility of insufficient global liquidity, confidence in national currencies being used for international purposes, and the existence of asymmetries in world monetary arrangements. Despite controversies surrounding these topics, political will demonstrated common effort for resolving core issues. In order to locate SDR within Bryant's (1995) framework, we would need to distinguish between what was initially aimed for and how things were shaped later. Initial goals indicated a wish for introducing a new asset with international character. However, as years went by, the resultant picture did not resemble the envisioned beginning. The initial SDR proposal would correspond to `mutual recognition in the context of an internationally monitored preemptive rule game.' This identification has two dimensions. In relation to international regime environment dimension, it suggests decentralized national decisions with weak monitoring by international institutions. As for the second dimension, there is information exchange, consultations, and bargaining in lower-level decision-making. At this front, we can describe the original SDR proposal to be with active consultations and exchanges of information (tentative efforts at cooperative bargaining). What has emerged as the SDR mechanism today? We can locate it between `national autonomy' (extreme) and `mutual recognition with infrequent consultations.' As the international regime environment, this description would correspond to decentralized national decisions with minimal international cooperation. With regard to the ongoing lower-level decision-making dimension, a correct description would be very limited contact, with almost no exchange of information or consultations. Unlike Keynes's (Bancor) and Gutmann's proposal targets, SDR acquired a role that appeared supplementary to the existent arrangements. Though it was truly an effort to find a cooperative solution to problems facing the entire world, it was left only a minor component in the system. For this reason (with national currencies in place), political economy concerns of monetary unions (in general) do not apply to SDR arrangements. Introduction of SDR and the subsequent progress brought almost no questions, such as SDRs affecting individual countries' monetary autonomy or seigniorage revenues. In an attempt to explain why SDR did not gain the initially envisioned role, the changing monetary structures are cited. One common argument is that new conditions emerged with floating exchange rates and increased capital flows, avoiding the need for expanding reserves. Eichengreen and Frankel (1996) refute both hypotheses. With regard to capital mobility, they note there are models that assert (with perfect capital mobility) the motive for holding reserves would be removed, but this result is reached under the assumption that countries can borrow at the world interest rate. Eichengreen and Frankel point out that this presumption is not true in reality, and borrowing is hardest for countries when they need reserves most (times of balance of payments crises) (Eichengreen and Frankel 1996, p.340). Furthermore, capital account itself can act as a possible source of financial instability. For countries with floating exchange rates, a high degree of capital mobility can increase the exchange rate variability and such countries would be more likely to hold reserves. Similar arguments for holding reserves obsolescence relate to movement towards floating exchange rates. Expectations were that more frequent adjustments of exchange rates through the markets would improve the scope for adjustment through relative prices against balance of payments imbalances. This mechanism was thought to eliminate the need for reserves. Yet following termination of the Bretton Woods system, countries continued to manage their exchange rates. Eichengreen and Frankel refer to the economic costs of large exchange rate changes as the main reason for government unwillingness to allow it happen (Eichengreen and Frankel 1996, p.342). Depreciation of domestic currency can lead to increased inflation rates and depressed output level through higher prices of imported inputs. It also can increase the burden of debt in foreign currencies and endanger solvency of domestic banks with liabilities denominated in foreign currencies. Additionally, exchange rate volatility itself would discourage international trade and investment. Eichengreen and Frankel (1996) suggest that the changing features of SDR are its strength. According to them, adaptability to new conditions is what kept SDR useful over time. Among many pessimistic comments regarding SDR's future, there are usually few lines noting positive aspects. One aspect is having a currency basket (like SDR) be a more stable unit of account than individual national currencies. Also, the financing provision for crisis management activities of IMF would be another proposed role for SDR. A development finance link is another proposal; this link remains controversial among countries. Its discussion is argued to be the most effective way of abandoning a new allocation attempt. There are valuable lessons to be learned from the SDR experience. First is that a world money proposal has so many repercussions; its creation and following implementation over time requires commitment from all, but especially the major players. If agendas of participants do not match, there are secondary means of stalling the functioning of the newly adopted structure. Keynes noted that as a requirement for a sustainable monetary arrangement, veto power cannot be granted to any country or group of countries. Secondly, while participation and decisions to leave are left to individual nations' own discretion, there is a prerequisite of intellectual consensus for achieving a change of this magnitude. Eichengreen (1995) notes this requirement in connection with changes in the history exchange rate regimes. SDR negotiations and subsequent implementation, despite stemming from a rather common understanding of problems facing the world's monetary system, demonstrate how differently perspectives are attained by different nations over time. Thirdly, although there were provisions to empower IMF for a lucrative functioning of the SDR mechanism, it appears they did not suffice in order for SDR to attain its stated goals. Fourthly, the language of the Articles seems to have caused confusion and provided room for avoiding action. There is a need for providing straightforward guidelines, instead of using phrases that may be interpreted differently. Identifying the time of additional allocations in vague terms, such as `when the global liquidity needs happen,' is an example. That did not provide a distinct criterion to step into when the need occurred. 5.3.3 Guttmann's SNCM Proposal We can observe issues reminiscent of the Bancor proposal and of the SDR experiences occupying a central place in Guttmann's proposal. He starts with the idea of the need for an institutional policy framework that will foster integration and balance, to counter the propensity for uneven development of current global accumulation regime. Therefore, the development link is a primary concern and is established from the beginning. Secondly, Guttmann also recognizes the use of national currencies as world money is an inherently unstable arrangement. He specifically points to the deficiencies of national currencies in relation to medium of payment and unit of account functions, when serving international transactions. He argues that a truly international medium of exchange is the next logical step in the historic evolution of the international monetary system. His reasoning for opposing the current multicurrency system enables us to observe new features added into Triffin's emphasis on reserve adequacy and confidence issues. Guttmann makes references to more recent observations, relating to the monetary system. These include deficiencies of the current system feeding into (chronic) external imbalances, volatile exchange rates, massive speculation, and an unstable global banking network outside the reach of government regulators. Guttmann's proposal has institutions, much like Keynes's proposal. An International Monetary Authority (IMA) is employed in both proposals for directing surplus funds to deficit spending. Again, he notes the mechanism's benefits in terms of providing a reliable funding source for developing nations while reducing risk exposure by surplus countries through lending to the IMA, rather than deficit countries directly. Further, it will allow observing borrowing totals of individual countries, to avoid overextension of credit and following crisis situations. If we were to utilize Bryant's (1995) categorization of international cooperation possibilities in the monetary sphere, Guttmann's proposal would be described as `strong activist coordination,' as was Keynes's Bancor proposal. Again, this identification corresponds to extensive joint decision making, with regard to the international regime environment dimension. In terms of lower-level ongoing decision-making dimension, it suggests frequent consultations with active searches for mutually advantageous bargaining. In comparison to the SDR and Keynes's (Bancor) plan, Guttmann asserts his plan aimed at achieving widespread use. For the previous two, he sees a limited role as an official reserve and debt settlement device, adversely affecting their ability to compete with other forms of international money. Hence, he is willing to introduce features that promote private use as well. CHAPTER 6 CONCLUSION Keynes's, Davidson's, and Guttmann's proposals, combined with the SDR initiative, all start with great ambitions and aim at structural deficiencies of the International Monetary System. They all represent attempts to find a new means of organizing the monetary affairs so that fundamental issues will be addressed, as opposed to hoping the temporary crisis management provisions will suffice. Structural aspects addressed through these proposals are centered around deficiencies of the multicurrency system. The dual role of key currencies as both national and international means of liquidity and `numeraire' for flows and stocks yields problematic results. Interest and exchange rates of these key currencies are critical in determining prices of standardized commodities such as crude oil, and value of international debt and assets. Despite significant international consequences, authorities of key currency countries are noted to act primarily on domestic concerns. Resultant policies are often associated with objectionable neglect, and at times overshooting adjustments. Many recent crisis situations are possibly explained in these terms as Schulmeister (2000) does specifically in relation to the dollar. It is true that changes on a substantial scale, like those proposed by world currency schemes, are harder to agree upon and are more intricate at implementation. Consideration of ideas relating to key questions is of utmost importance, so that a complete perspective is obtained. However, as the common attitude, many established relationships identifying the system are treated as a given and remain unquestioned. Particularly, supranational currency proposals are often dismissed with regard to political aspects raised as primary concerns. On the other hand, there have been episodes in history (such as Bretton Woods negotiations, emergence of SDR, and recent European monetary integration) when political will tended to converge on addressing issues, in order to reshape the system substantially. Extending those ideas, embodied in different perspectives, is a fruitful exercise for better assessments of both current arrangements and future possibilities. Among the proposals studied here, Keynes's Bancor plan is especially significant because of its context and subsequent influence on following proposals. Even though it did not prevail a winner at the Bretton Woods negotiation table, its impact on future theorists is noteworthy. Keynes introduced his plan in a manner that left some details open to negotiation. This demonstrates that a real bargaining situation demands accommodation of other participants' preferences. Despite being critical of existent arrangements (in many key respects) and proposing substantial institutional changes, presentation of the case less strictly is absolutely appropriate and necessary for opening avenues of dialogue on issues. With regard to the Bretton Woods negotiations and the Rio Agreement, the very act of convening to reshape the monetary system signifies that troubles of the monetary system can become so central that they will provide impetus action. Often times, when a crisis hits the world economy, the focus of policymakers (unsurprisingly) tends to be crisis resolution, and an analysis of the situation is postponed until clearer assessment is possible. However, the experience of troubling cases establishes the basis for modifying the existent arrangement so that successful functioning of the system can be attained. Whether any cooperative attempts to reform the international monetary system will exist anytime soon is a matter of political perspectives entertained by major players. The intellectual development leading to changing perspectives would be formed in response to failures and successes of the current system, and the new structures instituted. In that respect, current European monetary unification presents an invaluable case for analyzing many ideas included in the world currency proposals. This study explored political economy questions surrounding a limited subset of world currency proposals. These schemes incorporate a political agenda of new order, which is cooperation oriented. Even though each of these proposals starts by pointing at economic aspects and the proposed solutions are essentially aimed at relevant economic features, the connections to political issues are common. The ultimate drive is fostering a collaborative climate, both in economic and political affairs. All of the considered proposals stipulated an exchange rate arrangement of fixed exchange rates, with a possibility of future adjustments. When comparing the presented proposals, one feature is notable: they offer different criteria for exchange rate adjustments, when needed. Keynes's plan mentions it as one option responding to persistent balance of payments imbalances. Keynes stipulates a connection to efficiency wages when determining relative exchange rates of national currencies. Davidson's plan includes a connection to changes in efficiency wages, while Guttmann suggests a link to purchasing power parity. This may be a difference in the theorist perception for the critical determinant of exchange rates, and appropriate adjustment time. SDR's initial design also employed fixed exchange rates. Later, as floating exchange rates prevailed as the dominant choice, SDR's definition took the form of a currency basket. Unlike Bancor, IMCU, SNCM descriptions, or the initial intent for SDR, SDR acquired a role supplementary to the existing monetary structure. Meanwhile, with SDR's current role as a basket of currencies, SDR presents a more stable unit of account than individual currencies. In relation to all studied plans, it is safe to claim that employing structures to limit the scope for speculative actions in exchange markets is desirable - given the experience of recurring crisis situations in relationship to sharp exchange rate fluctuations. The value of international currency is tied to gold in Keynes's plan. This may seem contradictory, knowing of his opposition to the adoption of the gold standard in Britain. Keynes points to the introduction of rigidity if gold were to be used as a standard for the national currency domain. He argues for the use of gold as an international standard. In connection with its psychological value, and also for lacking another serviceable substitute, it would provide an uncontroversial standard of value for international purposes. How will national currencies be soft, if fixed exchange rates are to be set in reference to gold? He suggests that the ICU is expected to alter external values of the national currencies, conforming to internal values resulting from domestic policies. Hence, primacy of domestic priorities is established by assigning ICU to change external values of national currencies in tandem with domestic values. SDR, as initially envisioned, also maintained gold as the international reference for valuation. However, with its current definition as a currency basket, SDR's value is tied to the monetary and fiscal policies of major industrialized countries. Guttmann's plan describes SNCM with emphasis on the unit of account function. Thereby stress is placed on SNCM's functioning as a numeriare, and the relative exchange rates of national currencies (in terms of SNCM) create a relevant question. Guttmann argues for settling relative exchange rates of national currencies to reflect purchasing power of currencies. Meanwhile, SNCM is identified as an extension of national currencies, serving as credit money for international payments. Introduction of SNCM will not add to the total purchasing power of the world economy, since its utilization will correspond to equivalent reductions of purchasing power from the paying country's national economy. It would function like giving checkbooks to central banks of nation states and then transferring purchasing power from one nation to another whenever a payment is made. In the meantime, domestic policies of individual nations would be the basis for national currency values, as their values (in terms of SNCM) are connected to purchasing power differentials. Still, in Guttmann's proposal, there are other attributes that would be relevant to the valuation of SNCM. He envisions a system where the central agency, IMA, takes on a role combining both the World Bank and the IMF of current structure. IMA includes both the Monetary Department and the Financial Department, and the policies pursued by those authorities would affect the value maintenance of SNCM. For example, when IMA deems an expansionary fiscal policy appropriate for the world economy, extending additional credit lines may be the proper policy. In connection with that, the value of SNCM would be tied to the pursuit of consistent policies for rendering the value of SNCM as stable as possible. Distribution of seigniorage is another relevant issue. Keynes's plan does not stipulate any formula for distribution of seigniorage among member states. Nevertheless, the formula for determination of member country quotas would be relevant for seigniorage distribution as well. Usage of ICU's credit facilities and associated payments (on excess credit and debit balances) are tied to quotas of member countries. Any allocation of Bancors would accrue seigniorage revenues to member states in proportion to their quotas, and would partly relieve their excess balance payments to ICU. Guttmann's proposal also leaves the question of distributing seigniorage, by and large, not explicitly addressed. Stress on the unit of account function for new currency renders it without additional purchasing power for the world economy in the proposed scheme. With SDR, since allocations are made in proportion to IMF quotas of member countries, distribution of seigniorage is also tied to IMF quotas. An important aspect observed by Gunter (1996) was the effect of capital flows on developing nations. He suggested an asymmetry relating to impact of capital flow reversals. While both industrialized and developing nations suffer from exchange rate volatility, capital flow volatility is almost exclusively detrimental to developing nations. Every sudden reversal of funding flow leaves a wreckage of devastated financial systems. In connection with that, productive facilities are disabled by unexpected failures of banks and other firms with overall contraction of domestic economy. Structures watching the overall borrowing of individual nations, and means of monitoring the individual agents' actions are seen as a solution. With regard to capital controls, Keynes's plan lists them among alternatives for eliminating balance of payments imbalances. Further, the whole scheme of channeling member state international payments through ICU endows countries with the means of effectively watching transactions individually and overall. Hence, mechanisms for implementing capital controls are made available, and thereby application of capital controls would be an option deemed (at times) necessary. Guttmann's plan includes elements of strict convertibility restrictions. Capital controls would be an integral part of this plan. National currencies are restricted to circulate only within national economies. There is need for implementing stringent measures to avoid circulation of foreign currencies into hands of private users. In the meantime, the official channel for international payments through IMA would (again) set the course of effective controls on capital flows, as long as this channel is effectively utilized. In relation to capital controls, introduction of SDRs did not bring additional arrangements other than what existed with the Bretton Woods system and also (later on) during the period with managed floating exchange rates. During the Bretton Woods years, controlling capital flows can be seen as a requirement for the maintenance of fixed exchange rates, but addition of SDR did not establish any additional constraints then or during the following period with managed floating. An overdraft mechanism is put forth in Keynes's, Davidson's and Gutttmann's plans. In the case of SDR, a link to development finance has been frequently discussed. The former three plans are more favorable for Less Developed Countries in comparison to the current situation. There exists not only the overdraft provisions, but also features promoting equal terms of adjustment (between debtors and creditors) for balance of payments disequilibria. However, significant opposition is encountered for those provisions. In response to these objections, arguments referring to the overall picture are convincing. Overdraft arrangement introduces a truly multilateral character to international lending and borrowing. Keynes's analogy to the national banking system is not without merit. Both lenders and borrowers are likely to benefit from the establishment, in addition to introducing an expansionary bias to the world economy. Yet it would eliminate most intricate political choices of creditor nations used for determining creditworthiness. This appears to be the ultimate point of contention. Bringing multilateral features on international lending would correspond only to equity and efficiency improvements. Another significant aspect of these plans is the presence of special provisions, empowering the central international institution as a neutral nonmarket agency. These attributes include establishment of rules clearly in the beginning, and one-way convertibility conditions that give discretion to the international organization on specific issues. When the central agency is not equipped with adequate room for discretion on matters, or if a country or group of countries acquire veto power over decisions, the majority of participant countries would have insufficient ability to contribute on decisions. The SDR experience exemplifies how overall success may be tied to such additional specifications that would leave space for international institution's actions on implementation and consequent functioning. Political will is the key component for success in any initiative targeting of the monetary system structure. Since many repercussions will follow such changes, conflicts at the political realm are most likely to take place. Nevertheless, compromises at the negotiation table are often attainable provided the political will is attendant. Meanwhile, if we question how much yielding is possible, one notices that some of the economic constraints brought onto the table do not exist but are used as negotiation instruments. Or it may truly be that understanding perspectives of other participants will clarify the necessity of compromise. Political aspects of the studied proposals are the most critical elements to determine likelihood of possible adoption. This was true when the Bancor proposal was negotiated, and also when SDR was agreed upon. The same would hold true for Guttmann's proposal. With regards to the Bancor proposal, it was a time with intense political struggles among nations, as was marked by the continuation of the Second World War. Accordingly, negotiations at Bretton Woods and the resultant arrangements were primarily shaped by relative political and economic strength of participant nations. The decision to implement SDR also came primarily through political struggles. Sustainability of the gold-exchange standard was increasingly doubted in the face of U.S. manifested policies. Still, political power of the U.S. combined with concerns of avoiding crisis prohibited other nations from acting against U.S. policies. However, in 1967, there emerged a common stand to implement a new international currency. Nevertheless, the dominance of the U.S. at the negotiations was again signified by attributes adopted for SDR, and also through subsequent functioning of SDR. More recent proposals, like Guttmann's and Davidson's, would get a chance to be negotiated among nations only when the dominant nations favor such a scheme. The political aspects are fundamental elements in deciding potential for realization of all considered plans. The proposals considered in this study specifically have a common theme of the inadequacies of national currencies serving an international role. Furthermore, connections to development finance issues were made to demonstrate the potential of a well-functioning monetary system. It is this link to real economic changes from the monetary sphere that makes these proposals appealing since they attempt to introduce analysis revealing key connections. When we think about these proposals in the context of increasing world economy globalization, they indicate how certain primary concerns have changed over time, yet common issues persist. The globalization context corresponds to an environment where balance of payments imbalances are expected to come, in connection with the search of investment outlets for more efficient production opportunities. Therefore, as long as better productive structures are attained in the world economy, balance of payments disequilibria are considered inherent to the new context. Since more efficient worldwide production activities are desirable, the persistence of payment imbalances over the years would still signal a warning to the international monetary system, and the world economy as a whole. First of all, the current direction of imbalances does not fit the proposed new distribution of investments among nations and across the globe. Extensive flows of capital from developing nations, to key currency countries, display movement in the opposite direction. Persistent imbalances of key currency countries are particularly dangerous for satisfactory system functioning. Yes, there are increases in foreign investment to developing nations, but it is hard to conclude that this trend benefits the majority of the world economy (Sachs, 2001). Keynes's and Guttmann's proposals both started with ideas of instituting a multilateral lending scheme among nations. Such a scheme would increase efficiency in investment flows, in line with globalization, and fitting perfectly with current context. In Guttmann's plan, balance of payments imbalances are accommodated within the plan especially for developing nations. Reduction in their development gap is one explicit goal of the plan, as is the hypothesized consequences of globalization. One main feature is the attempt to commit the system to clearly-defined and symmetric rules. As a course for future studies, the connections from the current monetary arrangements to features relating directly to development gap between countries, trade patterns, distribution of international investments, and to pricing standardized commodities are promising. These studies can focus on specific aspects of the international monetary system, like exchange rate arrangements and volatility, or capital flow arrangements and volatility in relation to issues similar to the ones listed above. The common attitude of not questioning the system leaves plenty of prospects for study by those who feel there should be a better way of organizing the whole structure. Several arguments have been developed throughout the text. Reemphasizing some results of this dissertation is worthwhile at this final stage. For that reason the following subsection will provide a short repetition of some associations derived in this study. Reiteration of main findings. It has not been long since the world economy faced troubles across the globe after the 1997-1998 Asian Crisis. Other than the multifaceted suffering of many people at different corners of the world due to that catastrophe, its very happening signified how the interconnected nature of markets and production networks present real challenge to policymakers. Many national governments found themselves incapable of responding to international contagion effects, in the face of ever expanding world economy integration. Such detrimental consequences are symptoms of lacking an institutional framework for regulating the international monetary system. Within the current structure, the intellectual consensus mostly relies on temporary relief efforts and modification of a few features along the same lines as mainstream economic ideology. On the contrary, some success stories are told in glorification of countries that preferred to go against mainstream policy prescriptions. Malaysia applying capital controls after the Asian Crisis in opposition to IMF conditionalities is an example of possible better responses to situations as against to standard prescriptions of neoliberal ideology. This dissertation is an attempt to reveal some key features of the international monetary system, through a comparison of world currency proposals in reference to their political economy aspects. The main proposals considered in this study were Keynes's Bancor Proposal, International Monetary Fund's Special Drawing Rights, and Robert Guttmann's Supranational Credit Money proposal. This selection corresponds to distinct episodes in the history of monetary relations among nations due to the times these proposals were advanced. Comparing political economy aspects made a particularly fruitful exercise, in order to assess the features employed by each. Since conditions and problems of the international monetary system evolve over time, the changing attributes provide valuable insights into changing perspectives. The common starting point of the world currency proposals is discontentment with the use of national currencies for international roles. This characteristic of the international monetary system displays numerous conflicts between the two roles, both being played by that specific group of national currencies. Instilling faith in the decisions of key currency country authorities has not been an enjoyable situation for many countries. As such, the asymmetries imposed on the system are worrisome for all. The examined proposals are attempts to figure a new way of addressing below par performance. They all try to identify fundamental characteristics of the system with motivation to considerably alter them. Both Keynes's and Guttmann's proposals employ a neutral nonmarket agency, forming the center of a new institutional framework. From this structure, a multilateral arrangement is sought to facilitate the international transactions and lending among countries. Such a multilateral character to international lending is especially promising for more efficient and egalitarian distribution of possible funds. It would also bring symmetric features to the balance of payments adjustments (as stressed by Keynes) and help close the development gap between nations (as emphasized by Guttmann). IMF's SDR has also been discussed (in terms of possible uses) for enhancing development chances of Third World countries. However, those deliberations remained inconclusive for establishing a link to SDR allocations. It is argued that the most effective means of abandoning a new SDR allocation would be to bring this topic, a development link, to the discussion table. This only signifies how controversial this link has been among different groups of countries. One critical feature that emerges from comparing these three proposals is the importance of initially unanimous characteristics of the central institution. If the central agency lacks enforcement capacity, well-defined rules and procedures, the functioning may not turn out as expected in the beginning. The real experience of SDR exemplifies how the veto power of a country or group of countries may leave the central organization ineffective. Therefore identifying guidelines clearly in the beginning and the provision of enforcement mechanisms (leaving discretion to the central agency on appropriate aspects) are attributes needed for successful implementation. Again, the SDR experience illustrates the importance of political will by the participant nations. It is the most important contributing factor determining the feasibility of any change on this scale. Keynes's plan introduces some characteristics at the initial design, so that support of national authorities would be more likely maintained. Having finance ministers serve at the governing board of the ICU, instead of lower level technical personnel, would be a step towards sustaining cooperation of national authorities. The current trend of increasing globalization in the world markets and production networks has not been complemented by an international institutional framework for restructuring the monetary system. There are times when cooperative efforts intensify to resolve some conflicts, but the presence of significant asymmetries and persistent inequalities in the system point toward altogether rethinking the international monetary system. The world currency proposals represent a good starting point for analysis of what we want and how to achieve it. The current attempt for introducing a common currency at the European Union is especially valuable for predicting likely success of monetary unions. Deliberations surrounding this undertaking are informative for observing perspectives entertained by different nations and groups within them. A better assessment of monetary unions potential will be possible, in relation to probable success or failure at various manifestations. The overall success or failure of the whole experiment will be consequential in determining new distribution of economic and political power in the world economy. Subsequent changes of position by some currently dominant nations would not be surprising - if this challenge is perceived as real. Ruling out non-mainstream proposals in reference to narrowly identified political features is like avoiding understanding of the current system and shunning possibilities down the road. REFERENCES Abbott, D. 2000. The Case Against the Maastricht Model of Central Bank Independence. In The Impact of the Euro, ed. M. Baimbridge, B. Burkitt and P. Whymann, 226-31. New York: St. Martin's Press. Arestis, P. and Sawyer, M. 1997. How Many Cheers for the Tobin Financial Transactions Tax? In Cambridge Journal of Economics 21:753-68. Bryant, R.C. 1990. The Evolution of the International Monetary System: Where Next? In The Evolution Of The International Monetary System: How Can Efficiency and Stability be Attained, ed. Y. Suzuki, J. Miyake, and M. Okabe, 15-40. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press. ________. 1995. International Cooperation in the Making of National Macroeconomic Policies: Where Do We Stand? In Understanding Interdependence: The Macroeconomics of the Open Economy, ed. P.B. Kenen, 391-447. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Buira, A. 1996. The Potential of the SDR for Improving the International Monetary System In The Future of the SDR in Light of Changes in the International Financial Sysytem, ed. M. Mussa, J.M. Boughton, and P. Isard, 180-202. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund. Clark, C.M.A. 1999. Political Economy: Schools. Entry in Encyclopedia of Political Economy, ed. P.A. O'Hara, 2:868-75. New York: Routledge. Clower, R.W., and R.G. Lipsey. 1968. The Present State of International Liquidity Theory. In American Economic Review 58:586-95. Cohen, B.J. 1993. Preface of International Political Economy of Monetary Relations, ed. B.J. Cohen, i-xxv. Hants, England: Edward Elgar. Commission of the European Communities. 1990. One Market, One Money: An Evaluation of the Potential Benefits and Costs of Forming an Economic and Monetary Union. In European Economy 44. Cooper, R.N. 1975. Prolegomena to the Choice of an International Monetary System, In International Organization 29:63-97, and also in International Political Economy of Monetary Relations, ed. B.J. Cohen. 1993, 3-37. Hants, England: Edward Elgar. ________. 1990. What Future for The International Monetary System? In The Evolution Of The International Monetary System: How Can Efficiency and Stability be Attained, ed. Y. Suzuki, J. Miyake, and M. Okabe, 277-300. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press. Cumby, R.E. 1983. Special Drawing Rights and Plans for Reform of the International Monetary System: A Survey. In International Money and Credit: The Policy Roles, ed. G.M. von Furstenberg, 435-474. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Davidson, P. 1992. Reforming the World's Money. In Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 15:153-67 ________. 1998. The Case for Regulating International Capital Flows. Downloaded from the website http://econ.bus.utk.edu/davidsonextra/reg2.html on 4/08/2000. De Grauwe, P. 1988. Exchange Rate Variability and Slowdown in the Growth of International Trade. In International Monetary Fund Staff Papers 35:63-84. ________. 1996. International Money. 2d ed. Oxford, England: Oxford University Press. Eichengreen, B. 1989. Hegemonic Stability Theories of the International Monetary System. In Can Nations Agree? Issues in International Economic Cooperation, ed. R.N. Cooper, B. Eichengreen, C.R. Henning, G. Holtham, R.D. Putnam, 255 -- 298. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. ________. 1993. European Monetary Unification. In Journal of Economic Literature 31:1321-57. ________. 1995. The Endogeneity of Exchange-Rate Regimes. In Understanding Interdependence: The Macroeconomics of the Open Economy, ed. P.B. Kenen, 3-33. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Eichengreen, B., and Frenkel, J.A. 1996. The SDR, Reserve Currencies, and the Future of the International Monetary System. In The Future of the SDR in Light of Changes in the International Financial System, ed. M. Mussa, J.M. Boughton, and P. Isard, 337-77. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Feldstein, M. 1992. Europe's Monetary Union: The Case against EMU. In The Economist, June13,1992:19-22. ________. 1997. The Political Economy of the European Economic and Monetary Union: Political Sources of an Economic Liability. In Journal of Economic Perspectives 11:23-42. Fischer, S. 1982. Seigniorage and the Case for a National Money. In Journal of Political Economy 90:295-313. ________. 1983. The SDR and the IMF: Toward a World Central Bank? In International Money and Credit: The Policy Roles ed. G.M. von Furstenberg, 179-99. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Gilbert, E. and Helleiner, E. 1999. Introduction -- nation-states and money: Historical contexts, interdisciplinary perspectives. In Nation-States and Money: The past, present and future of national currencies, ed. E. Gilbert, and E. Helleiner, 1-22. New York: Routledge. Goodhart, C.A.E. 1995. The Political Economy of Monetary Union. In Understanding Interdependence: The Macroeconomics of the Open Economy, ed. P.B. Kenen, 448-505. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Gunter, B.G. 1996. Reforming the International Monetary System Towards a World Central Bank: A Summary of Proposals and Fallacies. In The World's Monetary System, ed. J.M. Greisgraber, and B.G. Gunther, 115-35. Chicago: Center of Concern. Guttmann, R. 1989a. The International Monetary System. In Reforming Money and Finance: Institutions and Markets in Flux, ed. R. Guttmann, 15-22. Armonk, New York: M.E. Sharpe. ________. 1989b. The United States as a Debtor Nation. In Reforming Money and Finance: Institutions and Markets in Flux, ed. R. Guttmann, 219-22. Armonk, New York: M.E. Sharpe. ________. 1994. How Credit Money Shapes The Economy: The United States in a Global System. Armonk, New York: M.E. Sharpe. Hahnel, R. 1999. Panic Rules! Everything You Need to Know About the Global Economy. Cambridge, MA: South End Press. IMF, 1995. IMF Survey. May 22, 1995, 153 and 163-65. IMF, 2000. Annual Report of the Executive Board for the Financial Year Ended April 30, 2000. Jefferson, P.N. 1998. Seigniorage Payments For Use of the Dollar: 1977-1995. In Economic Letters 58:225-30. Kafka, A. 1977. Comment on `Special Drawing Rights: The Link.' In The New International Economic Order: The North-South Debate, ed. J.N. Bhagwati, 101-04. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Kenen, P. 1992. EMU After Maastricht. Washington, DC: Group of Thirty. Keohane, R.O. 1984. After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Keynes, J.M. 1943. Proposals for an International Clearing Union. Reprinted from the British Government Publication, Cmd. 6437 in World Monetary Reform: Plans and Issues ed. H.G. Grubel. 1963. 55-79. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Lietaer, B. 1996. Global Currency Proposals. In The World's Monetary System, ed. J.M. Greisgraber, and B.G. Gunther, 94-114. Chicago: Center of Concern. Martin, L.L. 1993. International and Domestic Institutions in the EMU Process. In Economics and Politics 5:125-44. McKinnon, R.I. 1963. Optimum Currency Areas. In American Economic Review 53:717-24. Monticelli, C. and Vinals, J. 1993. European Monetary Policy in Stage Three: What Are the Issues? CEPR Occasional Paper no.12. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research. Mundell, R.A. 1961. A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas. In American Economic Review 51:657-64. ________. 1997. Optimum Currency Areas. Downloaded from the website http://www.columbia.edu/~ram15/eOCATAviv.html on 10/19/1999. O'Hara, P.A. 1999. Political Economy: Major Contemporary Themes. Entry in Encyclopedia of Political Economy ed. P.A. O'Hara 2:861-68, New York: Routledge. Rodrik, D. 1998. Symposium on Globalization in Perspective: An Introduction. In Journal of Economic Perspectives 12:3-8. Roosa, R.V. 1989. The Gap Between Trade Theory and Capital Flows. In Reforming Money and Finance: Institutions and Markets in Flux ed. R. Guttmann, 257-60. Armonk, New York: M.E. Sharpe Inc. Sachs, J. 2001. New Approaches to International Donor Assistance. Speech given at the International Development Research Centre, on June 19, 2001. Ottawa, Canada. Schulmeister, S. 2000. Globalization Without Global Money: The Double Role of the Dollar as National Currency and World Currency. In Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 22:365-95. Sinn, H.W. and Feist, H. 1997. Eurowinners and Eurolosers: The Distribution of Seigniorage Wealth in EMU. In European Journal of Political Economy 13:665-89. Smithin, J. and Wolf, B.M. 1999. A World Central Bank? In Global Instability: The Political Economy of World Economic Governance ed. J. Michie, and J. Grieve Smith, 212-26. New York: Routledge. Solomon, R. 1996. Creation and Evolution of the SDR. In The Future of the SDR in Light of Changes in the International Financial System ed. M. Mussa, J.M. Boughton, and P. Isard, 25-40. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. The Economist.1991. The IMF and The World Bank Survey. Oct.12th, 1991 issue. 5-48. Triffin, R. 1947. National Central Banking and the International Economy. In Review of Economic Studies 14:53-75. ________. 1957. Europe and the Money Muddle: From Bimetalism to Near Convertibility. New Haven: Yale University Press. ________. 1960. Gold and the Dollar Crisis: The Future of Convertibility. New Haven: Yale University Press. ________. 1966. The World Money Maze. New Haven: Yale University Press. ________. 1978. National Central Banking and the International Economics. In International Monetary Policies ed. L.A. Metzler, R. Triffin, and G. Haberler, 46-81. New York: Arno Press. ________. 1985. The International Accounts of the United States and their Impact Upon the Rest of the World. In Banca Nazionale Del Lavaro Quarterly Review 152:15-30. Verdun, A. 1999. The Logic of Giving Up National Currencies: Lessons from Europe's Monetary Union. In Nation-States and Money: The past, present and future of national currencies ed. E. Gilbert, and E. Helleiner, 199-214. New York: Routledge. Viner, J. 1929. International Finance and Balance of Power Diplomacy, 1880-1914. In Southwestern Political and Social Science Quarterly 9:407-51. Williamson, J. 1977. Special Drawing Rights: The Link. In The New International Economic Order: The North-South Debate ed. J.N. Bhagwati. 81-100. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. ________. 1984. A New SDR Allocation? Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. Wray, R.L. 1998. The Development and Reform of the Modern International Financial System. The Jerome Levy Institute Working Paper no.225 downloaded from the website http://www.levy.org/docs/wrkpap/pdf/225.pdf on 5/16/2000. Wyplosz, C. 1997. EMU: Why and How It Might Happen. In Journal of Economic Perspectives 11:3-22.